Skip Nav Destination
Close Modal
Search Results for
vent-for-surplus
Update search
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
NARROW
Format
Subjects
Journal
Article Type
Date
Availability
1-20 of 68 Search Results for
vent-for-surplus
Follow your search
Access your saved searches in your account
Would you like to receive an alert when new items match your search?
1
Sort by
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1996) 28 (3): 513–523.
Published: 01 September 1996
... thought have made more of the
vent-for-surplus doctrine than Smith ever intended. Or, it is quite possi-
ble that for advanced countries Smith never intended for his doctrine to
be consistent with his system of perfect liberty: after all, the surpluses of
commodities that he used as examples...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2015) 47 (4): 577–603.
Published: 01 December 2015
... countries,” the paradigm being “the typical case of a peasant
export economy.” Later, he suggests that “the vent for surplus theory may be extended on a
somewhat different basis to the agricultural surpluses of the advanced countries such as the
United States and the EEC countries” (1987b, 804...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1973) 5 (2): 438–448.
Published: 01 June 1973
..., Mass., 1926 ). Bastable , C. F. , The Theory of International Trade , 4th ed. rev. (London. 1903 ). Caves , Richard E. , “Vent for Surplus' Models of Trade and Growth,” in Trade, Growth, and the Balance of Payments , ed. Caves, Johnson, and Kenen (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1994) 26 (2): 267–278.
Published: 01 June 1994
.... Kurz , Heinz D. 1986 . Classical and Early Neoclassical Economists on Joint Production. Metroeconomica 38 . 1 ( February ): 1 -37. Kurz , Heinz D. 1992 . Adam Smith on Foreign Trade: A Note on the “Vent for Surplus” Argument Economica 59 ( November ): 475 -81. Marshall...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1981) 13 (1): 95–120.
Published: 01 March 1981
... as the ‘pro-
ductivity’ theory and the ‘vent for surplus’ the01-y.~It will be helpful to
draw on this distinction in the discussion that follows.
The ‘productivity’ theory
The ‘productivity’ theory was widely repeated in the nineteenth
century. John Stuart Mill, for example, in discussing...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1979) 11 (3): 406–424.
Published: 01 September 1979
... these ideas played a somewhat peripheral
role in classical theorking.” The vent-for-surplus theory does not fit
easily into Smith’s overall picture of the workings of the economy,5s
and the same might be said of J. S. Mill’s enthusiastic support of E. G.
Wakefield’s plans for colonies which...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2023) 55 (2): 205–213.
Published: 01 April 2023
..., with an Evaluation of the First,” v. 28, no. 3, pp. 441–58 Bruce T. Elmslie, “The Role of Joint Products in Adam Smith's Explanation of the ‘Vent-for-Surplus’ Doctrine,” v. 28, no. 3, pp. 513–23 Jürg Niehans, “Adam Smith and the Welfare Cost of Optimism,” v. 29, no. 2, pp. 185–200 Jerry Evensky...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1971) 3 (2): 238–264.
Published: 01 June 1971
.... This formulation flies in the face of the vent-for-surplus doctrine also
discussed by Smith (pp. 353, 359, 415) according to which the advantages of
trade lie in the market opened up for the products of domestic resources which
would apparently otherwise be idle, rather than in the more efficient use...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2015) 47 (4): 687–689.
Published: 01 December 2015
...
on the Corn Laws 151
Reinhard Schumacher Adam Smith’s “Two Distinct Benefits” from
Trade: The Dead End of “Vent-for-Surplus”
Interpretations 577
Norikazu Takami The Baffling New Inflation: How Cost-Push...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1977) 9 (3): 346–365.
Published: 01 September 1977
..., including the distribution of income and the allocation of
political power-a reflection of two circumstances: (i) peasants did
not produce a surplus adequate to maintain an influential nonagricul-
tural population, and the appearance of this surplus was a prerequisite
for the development...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2001) 33 (2): 345–367.
Published: 01 June 2001
... for commodities, consequently creating de-
mand for the work of the industrious classes (1:51–52).11
The farmers produced food and raw materials. Other people, who
lived on surplus food provided by farmers, were called “free hands”
(1:49).12 Manufacturers produced necessities of life as well as luxuries...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1985) 17 (4): 551–574.
Published: 01 November 1985
... of surplus value 111 where Marx is probably
referring to Ricardo’s $2, for he writes in connection with the existence of
skilled and unskilled labour: “Ricardo showed that this fact does not pre-
vent the measurement of commodities by labour-time if the relation be-
tween unskilled and skilled...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1980) 12 (4): 635–638.
Published: 01 November 1980
... output and money paradigms. He admirably investigates the
Smith-Say connections (pp. 16-19) but fails to discuss Smith’s non-Sayian
views, for example his vent-for-surplus concept. Unfortunately, .he also de-
votes little attention to the challenges to the Smith-Say-J. S. Mill paradigm...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2014) 46 (4): 609–640.
Published: 01 November 2014
... of production, still undeveloped in
their day. . . . . Profit to them is still amorphously combined with wages, or
at best appears to be a portion of surplus value extorted by the capitalist
from the landlord.”3
Since the last decades of the twentieth century, however, the view that
Cantillon did...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2016) 48 (3): 471–487.
Published: 01 September 2016
... of a purely theoretical interest,
as was done by Marx in his Theories of Surplus-Value, those Prolegom-
ena to any future history of political economy that will be able to present
itself as science.1
Even so, we owe to this renewed interest the publication of anthologies
that make the past authors...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2000) 32 (4): 711–732.
Published: 01 November 2000
...: to his mind market value was de-
termined by the “proportion” between “quantity” (supply) and “vent”
(demand), where vent depended upon “necessity or usefulness” (Locke
[1691] 1991, 244).4 In keeping with these principles, Locke held that the
“value of money” was determined by the plenitude...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2007) 39 (2): 307–312.
Published: 01 June 2007
... while the wage is still “ample,” thereby pre-
venting any further decline (though, of course, the stationary state would
be reached sooner than in the falling-wage case): “Were that accom-
plished, while the return to capital from the land was yet high, the reward
of the labourer would be ample...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2010) 42 (2): 221–266.
Published: 01 June 2010
... would remain idle is similar to Hla Myint’s (1958) later vindication
of Adam Smith’s “vent for surplus” theory of international trade. It dif-
fers from the Ricardian comparative-cost theory insofar as its emphasis is
not on the increase of effi ciency through the reallocation of resources...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2004) 36 (1): 163–186.
Published: 01 March 2004
... and the Determination of Economic Policy in Capitalist Society . London:Routledge. Robinson, Joan. [1942] 1969 . An Essay on Marxian Economics . London: Macmillan. Smith, Tony. 2002 . Surplus Profits from Innovation: A Missing Level in “Capital III”? In The Culmination of Capital: Essays on Volume III...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2001) 33 (3): 577–608.
Published: 01 September 2001
... 4 (June): 175 -86. Kurz, Heinz D. 1986 . Classical and Early Neoclassical Economists on Joint Production. Metroeconomica 38 (February): 1 -37. ____. 1992 . Adam Smith on Foreign Trade: A Note on the“Vent-for-Surplus” Argument. Economica 59 (November): 475 -82. Lardner, Dionysius...
1