Skip Nav Destination
Close Modal
Search Results for
nonrivalry
Update search
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
Filter
- Title
- Authors
- Author Affiliations
- Full Text
- Abstract
- Keywords
- DOI
- ISBN
- eISBN
- ISSN
- EISSN
- Issue
- Volume
- References
NARROW
Format
Subjects
Journal
Article Type
Date
Availability
1-7 of 7 Search Results for
nonrivalry
Follow your search
Access your saved searches in your account
Would you like to receive an alert when new items match your search?
Sort by
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2017) 49 (1): 59–92.
Published: 01 March 2017
... improved the paper. Any remaining errors are my own. Copyright 2017 by Duke University Press 2017 Richard A. Musgrave Paul A. Samuelson social goods public goods nonrivalry nonexclusion free riding References Atkinson Anthony B. 1987 . “The Collected Papers of Richard...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2015) 47 (suppl_1): 1–19.
Published: 01 December 2015
... of resources gives
rise to unpaid factors and attendant inefficient use; (2) “technical externali-
ties,” where increasing returns result in inefficiencies, including monopoly;
and (3) “public good externalities,” à la Paul Samuelson (1954, 1955), with
their inefficiency-inducing nonrivalry...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2005) 37 (3): 593–616.
Published: 01 September 2005
... assert that the arts produce “externalities,” or so-
cial benefits, which do. These social benefits extend beyond the buyers
and sellers directly involved in the transaction, and as such, are charac-
terized to some extent by nonrivalry and nonexcludability (Heilbrun and
This paper is a revised...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2005) 37 (4): 723–753.
Published: 01 November 2005
....
5. Conclusions
It is not claimed here that Kautilya understood the vertical summation of
individual demand curves or the concept of deadweight loss, or that he
developed demand-revealing mechanisms. However, he appears to un-
derstand the nonrivalry nature of public goods. He implicitly...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (1999) 31 (Supplement): 256–284.
Published: 01 December 1999
... definitionally
and in terms of the expenditure commitment) may not qualify. The
same could be said of national defense, however. If one adopts the
Samuelsonian definition of a public good—a good exhibiting (sub-
stantial elements of) nonrivalry and nonexcludability in consumption
—then art appears to fit...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2015) 47 (suppl_1): 174–198.
Published: 01 December 2015
... failure arose from the com-
bination of the very features that defined a public good—nonrivalry and
22. “I have not meant by these notes to take a stand in the contest between the Lindahl
theory and other approaches to a theory of public expenditures. I would agree with many criti-
cisms...
Journal Article
History of Political Economy (2022) 54 (1): 1–35.
Published: 01 February 2022
... referring to Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). Increasing returns to scale remained a bridesmaid but never a bride, as it had been throughout the history of economics, Samuelson (2001: 499) claimed.34 He was in a good position to appreciate the new emphasis in growth theory on the nonrivalry of knowledge input...