Abstract

As shown in a 2018 article by Cristiano and Paesani, the element of Phillips's 1958 article that immediately obtained attention in the policy debate was the estimate of the unemployment rate compatible with price stability. Building on this previous work and based on the unpublished papers of the Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes and other published sources, the present article throws fresh light on why the curve paper failed to influence policymaking. At least two reasons may account for this. First, by the late 1950s and early 1960s, works based on inferential statistics still failed to obtain widespread attention among professional economists in the United Kingdom. Second, Phillips's 1958 article came at the beginning of a process that led to the abandonment, for some time at least, of the idea of buying price stability at the cost of increasing the unemployment rate.

1. Introduction

In recent years, the early reception of Phillips 1958 has become a debated issue. After decades of tranquility, Forder (2014) provided massive evidence that the conventional textbook story of Phillips discovering a stable trade-off between wage inflation and unemployment, with the trade-off immediately adopted as a menu for policy, is only a “myth.” But Forder did not stop at this point. In his book of 2014 and many other writings (more recently in Forder 2019a, 2019b), he has insisted that Phillips's works are irrelevant in the history of economic thought and that Phillips 1958 in particular had no influence at all—a point of view that has been challenged by Laidler (2104), to which Forder (2018) forcefully replied, and more recently by Lipsey (2020).1

However, despite the disagreements that remain, a couple of essential points seem to be settled. It is now agreed that nobody ever thought to use the Phillips curve as a “menu for policy,” as the myth has it.2 And it is also commonly recognized that, immediately after its publication, and even though it eventually failed to exert any influence on current policymaking, Phillips's curve paper did elicit a (more or less) relevant amount of interest and discussion. As far as this latter point is concerned, the disagreement that remains relates to who immediately took interest in Phillips 1958, what of the curve paper attracted attention, and why it failed to have any influence on policy.

Leaving aside any general consideration of the relevance, originality, and influence of Phillips's works as an economist and focusing exclusively on the early reception of Phillips 1958 in Britain, it is on these latter questions that the present article has something new to propose. Building on Cristiano and Paesani 2018b and further archival research, it aims to present an episode that has been neglected so far and that, while confirming that the curve paper attracted attention, can also throw fresh light on the reasons why it failed to influence policymaking. As some answers to these questions have already been proposed, and as they point in different directions, a brief recap is in order.

Following a line of argument that can also be found in Laidler 2001 and that is largely based on de Marchi 1988, Forder (2014: 18–22) attributes the immediate interest aroused by Phillips 1958 to the “Popperianism” that was so much in vogue among Phillips's younger colleagues at the London School of Economics (LSE). The element of Popper's falsificationism that attracted the attention of the LSE youngsters was the idea that “science advances . . . by the framing of bold hypotheses, and subjecting them to tests” (Forder 2014: 19). The LSE youngsters who took part in the activities of the seminar titled Methodology, Measurement, and Testing (M2T) opposed this view to the more traditional methodology usually associated with the name of Lionel Robbins, a leading figure at LSE and the author of Robbins 1932.3 Whereas Robbins claimed that the intrinsic variability of economic circumstances would never permit economists to establish “universal laws” (Forder 2014: 19), it was precisely a law of this kind that Phillips (1958) claimed to have derived from the available data.

Among the young economists who were more attracted by Phillips's (1958) “Popperianism,” Forder (2014) highlights Lipsey, whose reminiscences as put forth in Lipsey 2000 confirm the point made by Forder. However, Lipsey has recently proposed the following account, in which a great emphasis is put on an element that, by contrast, Forder (2014: 12) dismissed as scarcely relevant:

What Phillips [1958] did was, by taking unemployment as a proxy for demand, to estimate that a relatively low rate of unemployment was consistent with wage increases equaling productivity growth so that the price level could be held constant. Rough and ready it may have been, but this was a measurement that no one else had thought to make and one that had dramatic effects. The hostility to Phillips' paper, particularly among Cambridge Keynesians, was I think because they thought this estimate would encourage policymakers to use unemployment as a means of controlling inflation. (Lipsey 2020: 11)

While Forder (2014: 12) has argued that “that sort of numerical estimate of what could be achieved was nothing very new and nothing special either,” the point made by Lipsey has recently found some support in Cristiano and Paesani 2018b.4 Moreover, the new evidence presented in the present article confirms that Phillips 1958 attracted a good deal of attention in policy circles and that this happened for its measurement of the rate of unemployment compatible with price stability at “a little under 2 1/2 per cent.” In this respect, more than a new hypothesis about the early reception of Phillips 1958, the present article provides evidence in support of an old one for which, for various reasons, little documental proof has been available so far. But the hypothesis proposed here is not new. It was sometimes proposed even in the “pre-myth” literature, although only sporadically, and not without some contradictions.

Brittan (1964), for instance, placed Phillips within a larger group of academic economists and economic experts at the Treasury who had recently argued, in different ways, that unemployment had to rise to stabilize prices. However, Brittan (1964: 295–96) labeled this “family of ideas” as the “Paish school” (mainly on the basis of Paish 1962), and quoted Lipsey 1960 and Phillips 1962 as examples of the “great deal of technical discussion” about this idea, but gave no emphasis to Phillips 1958. In contrast, writing much earlier (and before the publication of Lipsey 1960), MacDougall (1959: 377) noted that while Paish 1958 (later included in Paish 1962) “gave no very elaborate statistical analysis,” Phillips 1958 was at an advantage, as it “analysed the experience of the last hundred years.” But, again, a look at Dow 1964, a landmark in the literature on British policymaking, reveals that Phillips 1958 is barely mentioned. This, in turn, is contradicted by Hutchison (1967: 144), who highlighted Phillips 1958 as a “much discussed pioneer contribution to the debate on the causation of inflation” and quoted the passage with the estimate of the unemployment rate compatible with price stability at “a little under 2 1/2 per cent.”

A fragment from Knowles 1962, Knowles himself being another economist who took part in the story reconstructed below, may be of some help in making sense of these dissonant accounts. This is how Knowles recalled Phillips 1958 a few years after its publication:

In November [1958] . . . there appeared a piece of research [Phillips 1958] which carried political implication at this juncture rather than economic validity. The study purported to show that the rate of increase of wage rates could be “explained” (and therefore, others could suggest, why not controlled and regulated?) by the percentage of workers unemployed. That the methods used and the conclusions drawn were open to question was immaterial except to academics. (Knowles 1962: 513)

Knowles's brief account has something in common with the more recent one by Lipsey (2020). They both emphasize the deflationary implications that politicians and policymakers, more than economists, could have derived from Phillips 1958. The political dimension of the early reception of Phillips 1958, although sometimes reproduced in personal recollections at a later stage (along with Lipsey 2020; see, e.g., Brown 2000 and Holt 2000), is an element that has taken time to emerge. An endemic lack of evidence, and even some blind spots that will probably always remain, may account for this.

The role played by Phillips 1958 in Hutchison's and Knowles's reconstructions, for instance, is limited to the isolated passages cited above. These sources provide no evidence supporting what they say about Phillips 1958. Nor does Lipsey (2020) add anything more than his recollections in support of the idea that the innovative measurement of the unemployment rate consistent with price stability was the element that attracted attention to Phillips 1958. Wulwick (1989: 173) and Laidler (1989: 35n9) provide more details, but the information contained in these works comes from personal communications. More specifically, A. J. Brown (in a letter to Wulwick) and Richard Sayers and Alec Cairncross (in private communications to Laidler) revealed that Phillips 1958 was largely circulated at LSE before publication. The same sources also reported that in their evidence before the Radcliffe Committee (of which Sayers and Cairncross were members and who wrote the Radcliffe Report), both A. J. Brown, an authority on inflation since the publication of Brown 1955, and Robert Hall, head of the Economic Section at the Treasury, had Phillips 1958 in mind (possibly among others) when they expressed their opinions that there was no dependable relation between unemployment and inflation (Hall) and that the level of unemployment compatible with price stability could be very high (Brown).5 However, the name of Phillips is never explicitly mentioned in the Radcliffe Committee's published documents. And even when written records may have existed, these have not resurfaced. In his biography of Hall, Kit Jones (1994: 149) reports that “[Phillips] sent Hall a draft of his article for Economica” and that “Hall took a good deal of trouble replying to him.” The “article for Economica” was Phillips 1958, so this correspondence between Hall and Phillips would be an extremely relevant piece of evidence, but Jones gave no references as to where it can be found. And the list may continue with the “series of lectures . . . attacking the [Phillips] curve on theoretical and empirical grounds” that, according to Lipsey (2000: 236–37), R. F. Khan “was reputed” to have given and of which, to the best of my knowledge, no evidence has ever been found.

More recently, Cristiano and Paesani (2018b) have provided a more systematic account, based both on published sources and archival material, confirming that the measurement of the unemployment rate consistent with price stability is the element of Phillips 1958 that immediately captured attention in the policy debate. Cristiano and Paesani (2018b) also show that, when Phillips 1958 appeared, numerous estimates of the rate of unemployment that could stabilize prices were being proposed, usually with little or no explanation as to how they were arrived at—a lack of empirical foundations that certainly made of Phillips's measurement a potential game changer. Cristiano and Paesani (2018b) also confirm that, as reported by Lipsey (2020), some opposition to Phillips 1958 came from Cambridge, but they also show that important criticisms came from LSE. This happened early in 1961, when the LSE economist Henry Phelps Brown drafted a paper for the Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes in which the curve paper was strongly criticized. As this recent finding suggests, and the present article confirms, the council occupies a significant place in the history of the early reception of Phillips 1958.

Phelps Brown's paper on Phillips 1958 mentioned in Cristiano and Paesani 2018b is dated February 1961. Shortly afterward, Phelps Brown's comments on Phillips 1958 became one of the specific topics for discussion in a series of meetings with academic economists that the council held in May and June 1961 at the universities of Oxford, Manchester, Glasgow, and Cambridge, after a previous meeting at LSE, in which Phillips took part but that was more focused on a presentation by Paish.

To the best of my knowledge, this episode has never emerged so far, maybe as a result of the minuscule attention that the history of the council has received. In most cases, the council is given no more than passing references in the literature on British policymaking in the period of Conservative governments from 1951 to 1964.6 A complete history of the council, based on the several hundreds of pages of documents conserved among the Treasury files at the National Archive at Kew, London, remains to be written.7

For reasons of space, extremely selective use of these materials is made here. The brief history of the council in the next section is no more than a sketch of how the council evolved in the four years of its existence. Its focus is on how the council stimulated the debate on the existence and measurement of the unemployment rate consistent with price stability. This happened in 1957 and 1958, when the council's view was that unemployment had to rise in order to stabilize prices.

2. A Brief History of the Council

The decision to establish the Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes was announced to the House of Commons by Peter Thorneycroft, chancellor of the exchequer in the first Macmillan government, on July 25, 1957. In August, Lord Lionel Cohen, a law lord, accepted the chairmanship, joined by the economist Dennis H. Robertson and the accountant Harold G. Howitt. The establishment of the council is usually mentioned as an episode in Thorneycroft's stormy tenure as chancellor of the exchequer between January 1957 and January 1958. The salient aspect of Thorneycroft's chancellorship was the attempt to impose price stability as the primary objective, even at the cost of breaking the taboo of full employment. As all reconstructions confirm, this deflationary turn created conflicts within the cabinet as well as within the Treasury, where Thorneycroft's ideas were opposed by Robert Hall, head of the Economic Section, the group of professional economists who worked full-time as government advisers.8

Disagreements were so strong that on some occasions Hall expressed his willingness to resign until it was Thorneycroft who eventually resigned as the cabinet rejected his proposals aimed at curbing public expenditure.9 However, a point upon which the minister and his chief economic adviser concurred was that unemployment had recently been too low—and that, in part at least, this explained inflation.

As the council reports would confirm, throughout the 1950s, a continuous tendency of wages to rise faster than productivity, which produced what was called “creeping inflation,” had been endemic in Britain. In the attempt to stabilize prices, since their return to office in 1951, the Conservatives relied mainly on aggregate demand control. Meanwhile, following the recommendations of the white paper titled Employment Policy (Cmd. 6527) of 1944, maintaining “high and stable” levels of employment remained the priority. This situation put policymakers in a strict corridor, in which aggregate demand sometimes had to be cut to reduce inflation but could not be cut too much, lest this could result in high levels of unemployment. As a viable solution to the problem of reconciling stable prices with high employment, incomes or wages policy was sometimes proposed, but the white paper of 1956 titled The Economic Implications of Full Employment (Cmd. 9725) put a firm limit on this option by excluding direct intervention in wage bargaining. Incomes policy was thus reduced to frequent exhortations to wage restraint that obtained hardly any results.

During a meeting with the council held on October 22, 1957, Roger Makins, permanent secretary at the Treasury, presented this situation as “the background to the Council's appointment.”10 According to the record of the meeting, “Makins said that . . . the Government had been trying to operate a policy of persuasion inculcating restraint on all concerned in the inflation of incomes.” It was now becoming clear, however, that so far persuasion had failed and that new measures had to be adopted. In this context, the council's task should have been to convince the public that an increase in unemployment was necessary in order to reduce inflation. No consensus existed, however, on how much unemployment should have risen, nor was it clear whether an increase in unemployment was in itself sufficient to stop inflation. It was on these crucial issues that Hall and Thorneycroft were at odds.

Reduced to its operational terms, the disagreement between Thorneycroft and Hall pertained to the nature and measure of the rate of unemployment compatible with stable prices. Hall agreed that unemployment had recently been too low and that this corresponded to a situation of “over-full employment,” as he would also explain to the council on October 22. But while Hall was ready to support a limited aggregate demand reduction, he aimed at making price stability compatible with full (although not over-full) employment. The policy mix suggested by Hall included the adoption of a “guiding light” to prices, that is, an indication, based on the expected growth of productivity, of the maximum increase of wages compatible with stable prices. Thorneycroft, by contrast, put more emphasis on the need to reduce aggregate demand, even at the cost of higher unemployment rates. “We must be prepared to see the [unemployment] rate rise to around 3 per cent”—he wrote in a note dated September 7, 1957—“since unless we can get away from the idea that over-full employment must be supported at all costs we have no hope of curing inflation.” On his part, Hall feared that, unless some form of incomes policy was adopted, the necessary level of unemployment might be very high, probably higher than the 3 percent envisaged by the chancellor.11

In terms of economic analysis, the disagreement between Hall and Thorneycroft reflected the underlying debate between the cost-push theory and the demand-pull theory of inflation. That of Thorneycroft was a typical demand-pull response to inflation. Hall's view, on the other hand, was more nuanced. It combined a demand-pull element, the pull on wages exerted by excess demand in the case of “over-full employment,” with a cost-push factor, the push on wages exerted by the unions in wage bargaining. This view implied that removing excess demand may not suffice if no restraint was put on the cost-push factor. During the council meeting of October 22, Hall suggested that “a position of balance might be reached between 1 1/2 and 2 per cent unemployment.” Up to this level, he saw a situation of over-full employment in which inflation was unavoidable, no matter how the unions would behave. But when the “position of balance” was reached, the inflation rate came to depend on the unions' behavior, making wage restraint necessary. Without this restraint, Hall thought that the unemployment rate necessary to stabilize prices was “indeterminate.”12

When he presented this analysis to the council, Hall probably knew that it might fall on deaf ears, as the council's First Report would confirm. Published in February 1958, the First Report fully reflected Robertson's ideas as they had already been expressed on other occasions.13

The report blamed the postwar inflation “on an abnormally high level of demand . . . maintained for an abnormally long time” (Council 1958a: sec. 78), explicitly rejected the cost-push argument (secs. 88–89) and the idea of a guiding light to prices (sec. 109), and took a firm stance in favor of the idea that it was necessary to increase unemployment in order to stabilize prices:

The percentage of employees in Great Britain registered as unemployed, which was 1.2 in January, 1956, was 1.8 in January, 1958. No one should be surprised or shocked if it proves necessary that it should go somewhat further. In our opinion it is impossible that a free and flexible economic system can work efficiently without a perceptible (though emphatically not a catastrophic) margin of unemployment. (Council 1958a: sec. 135)

How large this “perceptible margin of unemployment” had to be, however, was not specified. The report admitted that there were “pessimists” who thought that the equilibrium level was much higher than the current level, while the council was taking “a more optimistic view” (Council 1958a: secs. 136–37), but not very much was offered in support of this optimism. In a context in which the cost-push argument had a large circulation, even within the Economic Section at the Treasury, the report assumed but did not demonstrate a demand-pull analysis of unemployment. No wonder, therefore, that much of the council's fame is due to the controversy caused by its First Report. It is on this episode that the abovementioned passing references to the council usually insist.

The archival resources shed some light on the events that followed. Soon after the publication of their First Report, Cohen and Robertson expressed their will to publish a “progress report within the next six months” and then to resign, and so did Howitt.14 The Second Report appeared in August 1958. Although it paid some lip service to full employment policies, it was a defense of the First Report and did not boost the council's popularity. Robertson eventually resigned in December 1958, to be replaced by Phelps Brown in February 1959. For a few months, Phelps Brown joined Cohen and Howitt, who had had to remain for lack of any viable alternative, until the publication of the Third Report in July 1959. Although admittedly in a purely interlocutory way, the Third Report opened the door to the various proposals on how to implement a “money incomes policy.” This novelty announced the U-turn eventually taken in the Fourth Report, published in July 1961, after the council had been suspended in autumn 1959 to be reactivated one year later with two new members who joined Phelps Brown to form a new council. Lord Heyworth took Cohen's place. Harold Emmerson (another accountant) replaced Howitt. After the publication of the Fourth Report, the council ceased to exist.

The Fourth Report was an innovative document. It positively denied that “appeals to restraint” could be of any use, and while admitting the need to get aggregate demand under control, it also denied that this might be enough “unless the restriction goes so far that the remedy is worse than the disease” (Council 1961: sec. 8). In its concluding sections, the Fourth Report insisted that a reform of the wage bargaining process was necessary and revived the idea of a guiding light to prices. It was well accepted in the press and government circles.15

In their history of the Economic Section, Cairncross and Watts (1989: 342) highlighted the report of the Organisation for European Economic Co-operation (OEEC) published as Fellner et al. 1961 and the council's Fourth Report as the two official documents that, for their resolute support to incomes policy, marked a turning point in economic advising. As far as the early reception of Phillips 1958 is concerned, these two documents also mark the defeat of the policy proposal that found empirical support in the curve paper. In the context in which it appeared, Phillips 1958 was a confutation of the cost-push argument and a piece of analysis supporting the idea that a moderate rise in unemployment would stabilize prices. However, most of Phillips's colleagues, and even some of those who were supposed to be more sympathetic to him on a policy ground, failed (or refused) to appreciate the methodological innovation that the curve paper was introducing. In part at least, this may have depended on a rather simplistic interpretation of the curve paper to whose creation Phillips himself perhaps inadvertently contributed.

3. Phillips's Curve Paper: A “Rush Job”?

The declared purpose of Phillips 1958 was to test the hypothesis that, exception being made for periods in which import prices had increased significantly, the level of unemployment and its rate of change could be used to predict the rate of change of money wage rates. Phillips took the unemployment rate as a proxy for excess demand, while the only cost-push element considered was the increase of import prices. As Forder (2019a: 591) points out, translated into the terms that were current in the debate, this corresponded to the hypothesis that the rate of change of wages depended on the interaction of demand and supply in the labor market, while the institutional factors related to wage bargaining had no effect on the dynamic of wages.

To verify his hypothesis, Phillips selected the period 1861–1913 as one in which, but for very few years, import prices had never risen significantly. If the starting hypothesis was correct, there should have been a stable relationship between unemployment and wage inflation in these years, which is what Phillips found in the first part of his paper.

Although the contents of Phillips 1958 are familiar, it is necessary to recall them before taking into consideration how the obtained results were presented in the curve paper and then received in the debate.16 On a scatter diagram in which each point corresponded to the combination of the unemployment rate and the rate of change of money wages for one of the years 1861–1913, Phillips connected the points in chronological order. In this way, the diagram points created “loops,” with each loop covering the period of one business cycle. The loops also showed a tendency for the rate of change of money wage rates at any given level of unemployment to be above (below) the average for that level when unemployment was decreasing (increasing) during the upswing (downswing) of the trade cycle. To obtain the average values around which the loops moved, Phillips divided the range of the unemployment rates covered in the diagram into six intervals. He then calculated the average unemployment rate and the average rate of change of money wages for each interval and indicated these average values with six crosses in the scatter diagram. Finally, assuming that each cross represented a fair approximation of the average rate of change of money wage rates for the corresponding average level of unemployment, he estimated the equation that fitted the six crosses.

Then came the second step. Phillips confronted the data on unemployment and the rate of change of money wages for the periods 1913–48 and 1948–57 with the values that could have been predicted using his equation for the years 1861–1913. For the interval 1913–48, the most interesting result was a confutation of the standard conjecture about the downward rigidity of wages determined by stronger trade unions after the return to gold in 1926. As Phillips (1958: 295) boldly pointed out,

The evidence does not support the view . . . that the policy of forcing the price level down failed because of increased resistance to downward movements of wage rates. The actual results obtained, given the levels of unemployment which were held, could have been predicted fairly accurately from a study of pre-war data, if anyone had felt inclined to carry out the necessary analysis.

For the years 1948–57, Phillips obtained similar results. This is shown in the table on page 298 of the curve paper, which is partially reproduced here as table 1. In the table in Phillips's curve paper, for each year, the first column reports the observed change in wage rates. In the second column, under “demand pull,” there is the change in wage rates predicted by the fitted equation for the years 1861–1913. This is followed in the third column by the “cost push” element, defined as the rate of change of wages that was necessary to keep money wages at pace with the cost of living as measured by an index of retail prices. Finally, in the fourth column, Phillips reproduced the change in import prices in the preceding year.17

Under Phillips's definition, the cost-push element could become effective only in those years in which the increase of wages due to the demand-pull factor was not sufficient to cover the increase in the cost of living. This had been the case in 1948, when wages had risen 3.9 percent instead of the predicted 3.5 percent. The figures for 1949 seemed to contradict Phillips's hypothesis, with an observed change of wage rates at 1.9 percent, well below the predicted 4.1 percent, in a year in which the cost-push element was at 2.9 percent. But, as Phillips noted, this could be explained as the result of the political support that the unions gave to Stafford Cripps, a Labour chancellor, and his policy of wage restraint. The observed data for 1950 (4.6) was in line with the predicted 4.4 percent. For 1951 and 1952, the rapid increase of import prices in 1950 and 1951 could explain observed data well above the predicted values. Finally, from 1953 to 1957, when the cost-push element was below the critical level, the table showed an almost perfect correspondence between the predicted “demand pull” increase of wage rates and the observed data. This latter part of Phillips's table is reproduced in table 1. For the period 1953–57, the correspondence was indeed remarkable.

Taken at face value, Phillips's analysis suggested at least two conclusions. The first one, although not explicitly stated, was that there was no need to resort to institutional elements connected with wage bargaining to explain inflation after 1952. The second and explicit one was that, assuming an increase in productivity of 2 percent per year, a rate of unemployment of “a little under 2 1/2 per cent” would have stabilized prices (Phillips 1958: 299). However, the way in which the curve was constructed, with the six crosses representing average values, suggested a less deterministic interpretation, in which any mechanical link connecting each level of unemployment to one level, and one only, of wage inflation would have to be excluded. Moreover, that the curve could not represent any mechanical relationship of cause and effect between unemployment and wage inflation seems to be altogether excluded when Phillips's previous works on stabilization, and especially Phillips 1954, are considered. Based on Phillips 1954, a rate of unemployment of “a little under 2 1/2 per cent” could never be a sufficient condition for price stability, but it may possibly be the target rate of a stabilization policy. Indeed, the only interpretation of the curve that seems to be consistent with Phillips's works on stabilization seems to be the one by Cliff Wymer, a friend of Phillips, quoted as a personal communication to the author in Bollard 2016: 170: “The relationship derived and estimated by Phillips was the locus of the long run equilibrium solution of a differential equation model. It was not a causal relationship and Phillips never suggested it.”18

Although reasonable, however, the point made by Wymer remains controversial. Desai 1975 was probably the first interpretation of the original Phillips curve as a long-run relationship, but it was rejected by Gilbert (1976), on the ground that it was more an application of Goodwin 1967 than a reconstruction of what Phillips had been doing while estimating the curve. In Gilbert's (1976: 57) perspective, Phillips's averaging procedure is taken to be no more than a “computational device,” deprived of any interesting “economic or statistical significance.” In their papers, however, Desai and Gilbert did not attempt to put Phillips 1958 in the context of Phillips's research agenda. When this has been done, for instance in Laidler 2001 and Hoover 2017, it has emerged that, if the curve paper is to be made consistent with Phillips's works on stabilization, Wymer's interpretation seems to be the one to be accepted.19 But, as Hoover (2017) has observed, the link connecting the curve paper with its theoretical underpinnings in Phillips 1954 is at best only “implicit” in Phillips 1958, which contributed to create the impression of the curve paper as a one-off endeavor, scarcely related to Phillips's main research agenda.

Only at a later stage, in his inaugural lecture as Tooke Professor at LSE on November 28, 1961 (published as Phillips 1962), did Phillips provide some indication as to the place that the results obtained in Phillips 1958 could have within his quantitative and dynamical approach to stabilization policy. In introducing the subject, Phillips argued that knowledge of the quantitative relations between economic variables that are either objectives or instruments of policy is necessary if the goals are to be obtained. Taking the unemployment-inflation relationship as an example, he assumed that, if any relation of this kind holds true, it will be valid “in given institutional conditions and on average over a period of years” (Phillips 1962: 2). Somehow distancing himself from the myth recently debunked by Forder, Phillips presented this relationship as a constraint rather than as a menu for policy: “Failure to take account of it”—he wrote—“may lead to the adoption of inconsistent objectives” (Phillips 1962: 2). Then, in a more specific section titled “Employment and Inflation,” he gave some afterthought to the curve paper, also in the light of other works that were now available.

In this section, Phillips (1962: 11) admitted that his attempt at measuring the relationship between unemployment and wage inflation in Phillips 1958 had been “very crude.” Comparing his assumption “that changes in the cost of living only affect wage changes in years when prices are rising rapidly” with the one made in Dicks-Mireaux and Dow 1959, Klein and Ball 1959, and Lipsey 1960, that “changes in the cost of living have a proportionate effect on wage rates in every year,” he also admitted that this latter assumption had proved to be “nearer the truth”—although he also claimed that, if this latter assumption proves to be true, it is necessary to take account that “changes in the cost of living are in turn mainly the result of earlier changes in wage rates and to a lesser extent of changes in import prices.” Finally, he suggested how his method could be combined with others' and employed for “prediction purposes”:

If these two behaviour relations are fitted to empirical data we can proceed to eliminate price changes and obtain a single relation expressing wage changes in terms of unemployment and changes in import prices, or alternatively we may eliminate wage changes and express price changes in terms of unemployment and changes in import prices. These new relations are not . . . behaviour relations, but they are valid relations for prediction purposes, and are indeed in the most useful form for prediction. (Phillips 1962: 11; emphasis added).

Phillips also pointed out that “the relation I obtained [in Phillips 1958] is best considered as a prediction relation of this sort,” and he concluded as follows:

If the other studies are also interpreted in this way there is reasonable agreement in the results obtained. It seems that if the average level of unemployment were kept at a little less than 2 1/2 per cent. the average rate of increase in wages over a period of years could be expected to be about 2 per cent. per annum so that with the rate of increase of productivity experienced since the war the average level of prices would be almost constant. (Phillips 1962: 11; emphases added).

Compared to Phillips 1962, Phillips 1958 made much bolder statements. It seemed to deny, rather than to assume, that the institutional element was important, and it put much more emphasis on the year-by-year correspondence between predicted and observed data, an eye-catching element in the context in which Phillips 1958 appeared. The council vicissitudes presented in section 2 clearly show that, when Phillips 1958 was published, the existence and measure of the unemployment rate consistent with price stability was a hotly debated issue even within the Treasury. As an observer who was on the spot would put it a few years later, “This question was the perennial, central operational issue of Britain's post-war domestic economic policy: the question as to the level of demand at which the economy should be run, as usually roughly judged by the criterion of the percentage of unemployment” (Hutchison 1967: 131). Put in this context, with no reference to its theoretical presuppositions (as in Phillips 1954, 1957) and no indication as to how the results should be interpreted (as in Phillips 1962), Phillips 1958 invited a simplified interpretation.

It is part of the Phillips curve oral tradition that Phillips considered the curve paper a “rush job” or a “wet weekend's work.” In most cases, these words are comments on the way the curve was constructed.20 However, it was not only, and probably not so much, the econometrics of the curve that made Phillips 1958 scarcely plausible in the eyes of its earlier critics. More relevant was that these critics and its leading supporter (Lipsey) concurred in considering it a mere statistical regularity, thus excluding from view any link with the theoretical underpinning that Phillips's works on stabilization may have provided. And also very important was that Phillips's (1962) own indications as to how his empirical results should have been properly interpreted came only at a later stage. Meanwhile, the almost perfect correspondence between the observed and predicted rate of change of money wages for 1953–57 is what attracted attention. From the M2T seminar methodological standpoint, this result was remarkable. The fact that the post-1948 points on Phillips's graph lay closer to the curve than did the pre–World War I data to which it had been fitted was a startling and extremely attractive example of a hypothesis passing the test of predicting observations that had not been used in its formulation.21 But outside the M2T restricted group of enthusiasts, the result Phillips had obtained looked very much like a pure coincidence. It could not be denied, but it did not seem credible.22 As a result, the immediate reactions focused on the estimated level of the rate of unemployment compatible with stable prices and were, on the whole, rather harsh.

Knowles and Winsten (1959: 114) described Phillips's “a little under 2 1/2 per cent” as “a gloomy pronouncement by present-day standards.” Moreover, looking at the data presented in Phillips's paper, Knowles and Winsten noted that the same level of unemployment could correspond to different rates of change of money wage rates. Considering how the fitted curve had been obtained, this was quite obvious. Nonetheless, as the next section will show, the same observation that can be found in Knowles and Winsten 1959 would later be made also by Phelps Brown in his council paper of February 1961.

A more vigorous attack came from Routh (1959). Routh argued that Phillips had based his analysis on an utterly unreliable set of data, one prominent observation being that the definition of unemployment had undergone several modifications since 1861. Moreover, as Knowles and Winsten lamented the complete lack of attention to the historical, institutional, and social changes that had occurred over the last century, Routh (1959: 299) accused Phillips of painting the picture of an “institutionless world.”

Significantly enough, even Robertson attacked Phillips on this ground. Phillips (1958) indirectly supported Robertson's demand-pull argument, but the former member of the council had little confidence in econometric methods. The proceedings of a conference of the International Economic Association held in 1959, published as Hague 1962, report this summary of Robertson's views:

Sir Dennis Robertson . . . did think that the econometricians had led us astray. The two concepts of demand pull and cost push were so intertwined that no econometrician could distil from the figures how much of price rise was due to the pull and how much to the push. . . . He hoped that econometricians would look not only at the state of demand but also at movements in it. The paper by A. W. H. Phillips did take that into account. This paper was very favourable to the optimists, but one could not put much reliance on the results because it assumed there was a fixed psychological function relating the attitude of trade unions to the level of unemployment over a whole century. (Hague 1962: 456)

Comments of this kind, so much in tune with old “Robbinsonian” methodology, betray a certain reluctance to follow Phillips on his new “Popperian” ground. One aspect, in particular, is revealing. To say that Phillips had ignored the institutional, political, and historical factors is questionable. He positively admitted that a political factor could explain the behavior of prices in 1949. Only, he found that, based on his empirical conjecture, there was no need to call into question these factors, or some change in any of them, to explain the behavior of wages after 1952 (and immediately after 1926). The reliability of his data and the accuracy of his measurement method could undoubtedly be put into question, but to say that Phillips had ignored the noneconomic factors seems to be a further misrepresentation of his work.23

On the whole, the early critics failed to appreciate what Phillips, for right or wrong, had been trying to do. Instead of using data to confirm some a priori argument, Phillips was letting the data speak for themselves. This aspect is strongly emphasized in Lipsey 1962, a defense of Phillips 1958 and a manifesto against “a priori arguments,” described as “inconclusive,” and in favor of using quantitative methods for the discovery of “stable, hence predictable, patterns of human behavior in the economic sphere [that] must be sought from empirical data” (Lipsey 1962: 109). Lipsey sided with Phillips, not because his analysis had proved watertight, as Lipsey (1960) himself had recently shown, but because he saw no other way of providing a “valid theory of wages” than starting from the data. From Phillips's (1958) and Lipsey's (1962) standpoint, Knowles and Winsten, as well as Routh and Robertson, were shifting the burden of proof. Reasoning on a priori ground, they were assuming, but not demonstrating, that there was some correlation between institutional, political, and psychological change on the one hand and the behavior of wages on the other.

Another way of criticizing the curve paper was proposed in MacDougall 1959. MacDougall gave due emphasis to Phillips's effort to come to a conclusion that was empirically based but noted that other works in which alternative hypotheses were empirically tested were now available, and, contrary to what Phillips (1962) would argue, according to MacDougall they pointed in a different direction. The first to appear after Phillips 1958 was Dicks-Mireaux and Dow 1959. While confirming that a correlation existed between unemployment and the rate of change of money wages, Dicks-Mireaux and Dow noted that it had become less evident after the war, giving more emphasis to the “pushfulness” of trade unions. Along with the already mentioned Klein and Ball 1959, another paper that appeared before the council tour of UK universities is Klein, Ball, and Hazlewood 1959. Both these papers were spin-offs of the preparatory work for Klein et al. 1961. To take account of the implications for wages of political change that had happened in 1952, Klein and his coauthors employed a dummy variable called F, representing the “political factor in wage bargaining,” this factor being that “the trade unions became more aggressive or militant in pressing their claims after 1952 under the Conservative Government” (Klein, Ball, and Hazlewood 1959: 5; Klein and Ball 1959: 467).

As MacDougall (1959) observed in his survey, taken together, these works suggested that Phillips was wrong: the rate of unemployment was not enough to explain the trend of prices in Britain over the last few years. And then came Lipsey 1960. As pointed out in Cristiano and Paesani 2018b, although it confirmed that a significant relation had been discovered, Lipsey's more detailed and accurate study put into question the possibility of reaching any definitive estimate of the rate of unemployment compatible with price stability, thus strongly weakening the most relevant policy implication that could be derived from the simplistic reading of Phillips's curve paper that was prevailing.

As this brief survey has shown, strong arguments were being put forth in the econometric literature that could be used against Phillips 1958. However, arguments of this kind were barely mentioned during the meetings with academic economists in 1961. The council seminars almost continuously remained on the ground covered by Routh (1959) and Knowles and Winsten (1959). With very few exceptions, the available econometric works remained in the background, and analogous considerations apply to Phelps Brown's “Council paper n. 126,” upon which the discussions were apparently based.

4. Phelps Brown, the Council, and Phillips 1958

As shown in Cristiano and Paesani 2018b, among the Phelps Brown papers conserved in the LSE archives, there is the typescript of a paper, “Notes on Causes of the Movement of Money Wages in Recent Years,” dated February 24, 1961, that served the purpose of dismantling Phillips's (1958) argument. A copy of the same document is extant among the council papers at the National Archives, cataloged as “Council paper n. 126” (in T 178/5). Documents in another file (T 178/14) seem to suggest that Council paper n. 126 (or, maybe, a redraft of this document) was included as “Paper 3” in a set of six papers that were circulated as the basis for discussion during the meetings that the council held at Oxford, Glasgow, Manchester, and Cambridge in May and June 1961.24 If these meetings had any effect, this was to reinforce Phelps Brown's conclusion that Phillips's estimate of the equilibrium rate of unemployment was unreliable; a previous meeting held at LSE, in which Phillips was present, could not do much to change the situation.

In Council paper n. 126, Phelps Brown used the median rate of unemployment and the median rate of change of earnings in 130 industries to show that, even though there were significant differences between industries, a Phillips-like relation between unemployment and the rate of change in earnings was, on the whole, roughly confirmed.25 The problem was that, replicating the view already expressed in Phelps Brown 1958, such a relation was not “dependable” enough to make it a guide for policy. It is clear from the following and other passages from Council paper n. 126 that are quoted below that the idea of Phillips's fitted curve as the locus of long-run equilibria was completely alien to Phelps Brown, nor did he consider the possibility that Phillips's results could be valid “on average over a period of years,” as Phillips (1962) would later suggest:

If there were a dependable relation between the level of unemployment and the rate of rise in money earnings, we might expect there to be a level of unemployment at which the rise of money earnings would be low enough to avoid inflation. . . . Such observations have suggested that inflation can be avoided while bargaining goes on just as it does now, if only effective demand can be adjusted so that the pressure on resources does not exceed an intensity indicated by an unemployment rate of, say, rather less than 2 1/2 per cent. But there are several reasons for doubting whether there is in fact any continuous quantitative relation, on which the authorities could rely, between the unemployment rate and the rise of money wages. (Council paper n. 126, in T 178/5)

To show that no “continuous quantitative relation, on which the authorities could rely,” existed, Phelps Brown made no mention of the existing econometric literature, even though it is implausible that he did not know at least the few papers mentioned above. His way of reasoning, in any case, was much more akin to Routh (1959) and Knowles and Winsten (1959) than to, say, Klein and Ball (1959) or Lipsey (1960). Just as Knowles and Winsten (1959) had done, he noted that just looking at “Prof. Phillips's materials,” one could observe that “for example, an unemployment rate of about 1 1/2 [per cent] has been associated since the war with six different rates of rise in wage-rates, varying from under 2 to over 10 per cent a year.”

As pointed out in section 3 above, this contradiction between the data employed in Phillips 1958 and the straightforward policy prescription that seems to derive from the curve becomes more apparent than real once the way the curve was constructed or its relation to Phillips's previous work on stabilization is taken into consideration. Moreover, it is unlikely that Phelps Brown, who is credited (see Lipsey 2000: 234–35; 1978: 50) with providing the data employed in Phillips 1958 and who was in close contact with Phillips at LSE, was unaware of Phillips's research on stabilization. On the other hand, it must be observed that when Phillips was given the opportunity to make the link connecting the curve to his own research on stabilization more explicit, he apparently failed to do so. As a prologue to the tour outside London, the council took the opportunity to discuss these topics directly with Phillips, among others. This happened in the sixty-seventh meeting with witnesses, which the council held at LSE on March 21, 1961.26 However, it seems that not even on this occasion did the link connecting Phillips 1958 to Phillips 1954 emerge.27

The record reports that the meeting began with a “seminar” by Paish and that “Professor Phillips then followed suit.” The topic of Paish's seminar was a memorandum on the proposal, which is analogous to Phillips's equilibrium rate of unemployment, that in order to stop inflation, it was necessary to accept “a margin of unused capacity.” It is not clear with which topic Phillips “followed suit.” Judging from the “conclusions” at which he is reported to have arrived, this included those institutional aspects that he allegedly ignored in the curve paper and that would find renewed consideration in Phillips 1962:

Professor Phillips came to the conclusion that our present method of determining wages falls between two stools; if we had either bargaining by smaller units or, conversely, a national wages policy, then we might be able to secure stable prices with an unemployment rate rather lower than 2 to 2 1/2 per cent. . . .

Professor Phillips agreed with the Chairman that earnings do in fact differ in different parts of the country, and repeated that this meant we now get the worst of both worlds: a wage round and competitive bidding up in many areas.

Nevertheless, the relation between wage inflation and unemployment was certainly discussed:

Professor Phelps Brown said that one of the reasons why he had difficulty in accepting the theories put forward by Professor Paish and Professor Phillips was that the higher unemployment rates in this country during the period 1956/58 did not seem to have had the sort of effect that the theory suggested; nor was the effect to be seen in other countries, notably the United States and Denmark, where unemployment was often much higher than in Britain. Dr. Lipsey said he agreed that in this country unemployment had not been held at a level of 2 per cent for long enough to draw conclusions; but he thought that what evidence there was supported the ideas of Professor Paish and Professor Phillips.

That Phillips's results had to be considered valid on average is at least implicit in Lipsey's remark. However, based on the record of the meeting, all that Phillips would have said in reply to Phelps Brown is what follows: “Professor Phillips said he had done some work on the past relationship of unemployment and wage increases in the United States and Australia, and the connection seemed fairly good.”

As far as Australia is concerned, this probably refers to Phillips (1959) 2000, a replica of the curve paper based on data on Australia in which more refined methods of analysis were employed. Phillips presented this work at the economics department of the University of Adelaide but never submitted it for publication. As pointed out by Bollard (2016: 172–73), in part at least, this reluctance to publish the Australian paper may have resulted from the severe criticism received at Adelaide. Moreover, Bollard argues that Phillips's interest in this kind of research faded away after 1959. However, the record of the council meeting at LSE in 1961, in which Phillips also referred to similar work he had been doing on US data, seems to show that, at this date, Phillips may have not yet completely abandoned this line of research. Moreover, the same evidence apparently confirms that Phillips was reluctant to connect the line of empirical research pursued in Phillips 1958 to his theoretical work on stabilization. In the event, this link never emerged, neither during the meeting at LSE nor in the other meetings with academic economists.

Another thing that these meetings reveal has more to do with Phelps Brown. Unlike Robertson before him, Phelps Brown was extremely careful in collecting the opinions of his fellow economists, at least on the most relevant topics, before putting his signature on the council's Fourth Report. An important decision the new council had to make concerned the proposal, made in the First Report, of raising unemployment to stabilize prices. In the end, undoubtedly influenced by Phelps Brown, the council positively rejected this policy. Furthermore, the meetings with economists seem to show that, while Phillips 1958 had become representative, at least in the council proceedings, of the idea of buying price stability at the cost of more unemployment, Phelps Brown received considerable support in rejecting that idea.

At Nuffield College, Oxford, on May 18, 1961, the participants were the warden (Norman Chester), P. W. S. Andrews, T. Balogh, J. R. Hicks, E. F. Jackson, K. G. J. C. Knowles (of Knowles 1962 and Knowles and Winsten 1959), I. M. D. Little, Sir Donald MacDougall (of MacDougall 1959), C. R. Ross, and G. D. N. Worswick. The record reports that when “the meeting . . . turned to the paper on ‘Causes of the Movement of Money Wages in Recent Years’ (Paper 3),” “Mr Jackson said that the theories of Professor Phillips on the relationship between unemployment and wage increases were not worth considering. Mr. Balogh said he thought there was no systematic relationship between earnings and rates; one could not say that movements in the one caused movements in the other in any predictable way.” After these remarks, the discussion momentarily turned to an exchange of opinions between Worswick, Knowles, and Phelps Brown on the relationship between rates and earnings in different industries. Then, one of the council members (Emmerson) brought the discussion back on track:

Sir Harold Emmerson asked if there was general agreement that variations in the unemployment rate did not, except within pretty wide limits, have very much effect on the rate of increase of wages. This proposition was generally agreed to, but a number of comments were put forward. Sir Donald MacDougall said that he thought it would be a mistake to suppose that the rate of increase of wages was totally insensitive to movements in the unemployment rate, and Professor Hicks agreed with this. Sir Donald thought that the last sentence on page 5 looked rather odd, and would be unfortunate if published in its present form.

Unfortunately, it has not been possible to identify “the last sentence on page 5” mentioned by MacDougall. Even if the contents of Paper 3 mentioned in the record corresponds, as it seems plausible, to those of Phelps Brown's Council paper n. 126 (or some variation of it), we do not know in which form this paper was transmitted to the members of Nuffield College.28 Further doubts emerge from the record of a restricted meeting that the council held the morning after, before leaving from Nuffield College. In the summary of this meeting (in T 178/16), there is this sentence: “It was felt that the reactions to Professor Phillips's ideas had been interesting, and it was noted, in view of the way the sentence about a 3 per cent unemployment rate had been picked on in the seminar, that in its Report the Council would have to phrase very carefully any reference to the advantages or otherwise of using unemployment as a weapon to fight inflation.”

Once again, it is not clear where this “sentence about a 3 per cent unemployment rate” comes from. Neither Phelps Brown's paper nor the record of the meeting with the Oxford economists includes such a sentence. Nonetheless, even though a complete reconstruction of the events is not possible, the message that the council received at Oxford is clear, nor did it change at Glasgow University, where T. Johnston and I. Stewart from Edinburgh University joined A. K. Cairncross, D. J. Robertson, T. Wilson, and J. R. Parkinson to meet the council on May 23, 1961.

Not surprisingly, at least Parkinson expressed some support for Phillips: “Mr. Parkinson said that he disagreed with the scepticism expressed about Professor Phillips's basic premise; he thought there was a relationship between unemployment and the rate of increase of wages.” Parkinson was a convinced supporter of the demand-pull school and the author of the leading contribution in the symposium on inflation edited by Cairncross and published in the Scottish Journal of Political Economy in 1958. Even more than in the symposium, however, his voice remained isolated. As far as the summary of the meeting can show, a reply to Parkinson came from Phelps Brown, who said that “he agreed that very high or very low unemployment had an effect on the rate of increase of wages; but it was much less obvious that there was a relationship over the intervening range of unemployment.” As it seems, while no one replied to this argument, the discussion continued with some remarks on a hypothesis, introduced by Phelps Brown, that “a given level of unemployment might have a different effect on the rate of increase of wages according to whether it had just been reached, or had been in operation for some time.” This was a rare occasion in which the idea that Phillips's “a little under 2 1/2 per cent” might become the target of a stabilization policy was at least adumbrated. But after a few remarks on this point by D. J. Robertson, Heyworth, and Cairncross, the meeting moved on to another topic.

The day after, May 24, the council was at Manchester University to meet C. F. Carter, J. Johnston, B. R. Williams, H. A. F. Turner, R. J. Ball (of Klein and Ball 1959), E. M. Hugh Jones (from Keele), A. J. Brown (from Leeds), and (from Liverpool) G. L. S. Shackle and F. E. Hyde.

Not surprisingly, when the participants began to discuss “the paper on Causes of Movements of Money Wages in recent years (Paper 3),” Ball had something to say:

Mr. Ball said that there was no reference in this paper to the kind of multi-variate analysis which had been carried out by Dicks-Mireaux and Dow, and also by Ball and Klein. This econometric approach treated the demand for labour as only one factor affecting the rate of increase of wages; and it also incorporated feed-back mechanisms, such as the effect on wages of rising prices. Work of this kind suggested that the fall in demand needed to curtail excessive wage increases would be so large that it would entail a very substantial fall in production.29

Stimulated by this remark, Phelps Brown this time decided to follow the econometrician on his ground:

Professor Phelps Brown asked whether the more detailed work of Ball and Klein had different implications for policy from the work of Dicks-Mireaux and Dow, and Mr. Ball said it did not. He agreed that both studies suggested that excess demand works directly in the labour market, by causing earnings to rise, and not in a round-about way via prices. He thought that his analysis of the mechanism at work during the period 1948–56 showed that some inflation was inevitable as long as full employment was maintained. He agreed with Professor Carter that this could be changed only by a change in institutions and habits.

In this way, based on the most advanced econometric analyses (which, as it seems, did not include Phillips 1958), Ball was expressing a critical point that would also recur in the Fourth Report. If full employment and price stability were to coexist, the control of demand was a necessary but not a sufficient condition, and some change of “institutions and habits” (i.e., of wage bargaining) was in order. However, as the following extract from the summary of the discussion confirms, it was still too soon for these choices to be based on econometric studies:

Professor Carter said the difficulty about an econometric model was that its parameters were inevitably derived from past experience; it could therefore give no guidance about the consequences of any institutional change. Professor Johnston agreed with this, but said that we were still a long way off knowing enough about the effects of particular changes within the present institutional framework. The Chairman [Heyworth] said he thought that until econometric models had got much better at quantifying the various intangible factors that were so important in this field we should have to rely on a more immediately practical approach. Mr. Turner agreed that it was very difficult to quantify in a model factors like Government's attitude, the pushfulness of particular Trade Unions, and so on.

Econometric studies were barely beginning to enter the debate. At Cambridge, during the meeting held on June 8, there was the following exchange between A. Robinson, Kahn, and W. A. B. Reddaway: “Professor Robinson asked what determined the point, in terms of unemployment, at which wage-push inflation started. Professor Kahn said that the Dow and Dicks-Mireaux analysis suggested the degree of trade union pushfulness as one factor that affected this, but Mr. Reddaway thought that one should be very careful in interpreting the Dow-Dicks analysis.”

However, even on this occasion, the discussion was soon brought back onto a more “realistic” (or descriptive) track, in this case by Emmerson, who “said that one very important factor was the personality of the leading figures involved in wage negotiations at different times.”

Along with A. Robinson, Kahn, and Reddaway, the other Cambridge University members who were present were J. E. Meade and J. R. Stone. On Paper 3, Kahn had no doubts. He “said he certainly agreed with the paper's rejection of Professor Phillips's theories, which were based on data relating to cyclical movements, and provided no information about what might happen if a higher rate of unemployment was permanent.” To this, Robinson is reported to have added that “one should also consider how very low the rate of growth would probably be if one had to damp down demand every time unemployment fell below the relatively high level that Professor Phillips's model suggested.”

The questions that emerged at Cambridge, raised by Kahn and A. Robinson, pertained exactly to the stabilization problems that Phillips was investigating in the works that he did not mention in the curve paper and that, at least in the evidence considered in the present reconstruction, never resurfaced in the early debate on Phillips 1958.

5. Concluding Remarks

Eighteen years after the publication of Phillips 1958, and one year after Phillips's death in 1975, Blackaby (1976) observed that, over the prior two decades, the use of quantitative methods in macroeconomic policy had increased dramatically. In the same paper, Blackaby reconstructed the slow but continuous rise of the maximum level of unemployment that was considered tolerable from a political point of view. Indirectly, Blackaby suggests that Phillips 1958 appeared at too early a stage of both processes. The “a little under 2 1/2 per cent” equilibrium rate of unemployment was still too high for the standards of 1958. In the same vein, between 1958 and 1961, the use of inferential statistics and quantitative methods in the policy debate was still in its infancy. Both elements put Phillips at a disadvantage. Nonetheless, combined with the evidence presented in Cristiano and Paesani 2018b, the present article has shown that the curve paper certainly played a significant role in the policy debate.

A further tentative conclusion that can be derived from the reconstruction presented in this article is that the role played by Phillips in the policy debate was perhaps the unintended consequence of a rather simplistic interpretation of his curve that Phillips himself had inadvertently favored. Maybe by mere coincidence, but certainly with an innovative method, Phillips had produced an equation, based on data from a distant period, that was apparently able to predict the rate of change of wages forty years hence. This may have created a kind of “magic formula effect,” something that gave him the feeling that he had put his finger on something but that particularly irritated many of his early readers. Building on Cristiano and Paesani 2018b, the present article has investigated the reactions of these readers and their main consequences, which were to give Phillips a certain amount of visibility in the policy debate while at the same time helping to propagate a rather simplistic interpretation of the curve paper. On the other hand, that Phillips had put his finger on something was probably true. At least, he had indicated a possible direction that empirical research could take. And he had also shown, unintentionally, that there was an increasing demand for empirically based works on policy issues, as Blackaby would later confirm.

If there was an obstacle in the way of empirically based economics, this might have been on the supply side. In this respect, what the council seminars on the whole convey is the existence of a bias against econometrics, a negative attitude that Phillips's (1958) too bold and “crude” statements may certainly have reinforced. In most cases, what attracted attention was either the data employed by Phillips, the conclusions inferred from these data, or both. But almost no one among the economists who took part in the council seminars ever entered into the econometrics of the curve paper. Borrowing from Forder's interpretation, it was as if the “Popperian” element of Phillips 1958, which was certainly to be found in the econometrics of the curve, was looked at through the lens of Robbins's (1932) methodology. The result was that, on the whole, the innovative methodological element that had attracted attention among the LSE youngsters was not even actually rejected but, more simply, bypassed and therefore ignored by the other economists.

The author wishes to thank Massimo Di Matteo, Paolo Paesani, two anonymous referees, and the editor of this journal for their useful comments and suggestions on earlier drafts of the article. The usual disclaimer applies.

Notes

1.

In his book, Forder (2014: 10) argued that “despite a couple of exquisite papers (Phillips 1954, 1957), [Phillips] had practically no influence at all,” that “Phillips (1958) in particular was a negligible paper,” and that “in understanding the development of economic thought, if one were commencing with a clean sheet, Phillips’ paper would be ignored.” In his review of Forder 2014, Laidler (2014) rejected this view as invalid: “To infer, as Forder does, that Phillips’s paper was ‘negligible’ and had ‘very little impact,’ with memories of it living on mainly in the label ‘Phillips curve,’ is simply not true.” More recently, Forder’s views on the negligible influence of Phillips 1958 have been replicated in Forder 2019a and Forder 2019b. The latter contribution, which also replicates Forder’s views on the slight relevance of Phillips as an economist, has been challenged by Lipsey (2020).

2.

According to Laidler (2014), “Forder is completely right” in arguing that “there is not a shred of evidence that macroeconomic policy anywhere attempted to exploit an inflation unemployment trade-off in the 1960s.” Lipsey (2020: 11) has recently joined in by arguing that he agrees “with Forder that there is no evidence that the curve had any significant effect on subsequent economic policy.”

3.

See also Thomas 2009 and Bollard 2016: 167–68.

4.

In Forder’s (2014) broader perspective, some details are inevitably lost. One of these details is that, when Phillips 1958 was published, the existence, stability, and measurement of an unemployment rate compatible with price stability was attracting increasing attention at top political levels, as shown in sec. 2 below, as well as among academic economists (more on this in Cristiano and Paesani 2018a, 2018b). When these elements are brought into the picture, however, Forder’s main argument remains valid, and it is even strengthened. In the events reconstructed in the present article, as well as in Cristiano and Paesani 2018b, Phillips 1958 was never considered as a piece of analysis suggesting that policymakers buy employment at the cost of rising inflation, as the myth would suggest. Indeed, it was received (in most cases, unfavorably) as a piece of analysis in support of deflationary policy. The same point is also made, although not very much developed, in Forder 2019a.

5.

The Committee on the Working of the Monetary System (Radcliffe Committee) was appointed by Peter Thorneycroft, chancellor of the exchequer (minister of finance), in May 1957 “to enquire into the working of the monetary and credit system, and to make recommendations.” Its Report (Cmnd. 827), the three volumes containing the Principal Memoranda of Evidence, and a volume with the Minutes of Evidence were published in 1960. Its story ran parallel to that of the Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes, on which more details are given below. On the debate on inflation during the proceedings of the Radcliffe Committee, see also Cristiano and Paesani 2018a.

6.

See Brittan 1964: 188; Dow 1964: 99; Hutchison 1967: 137; Cairncross and Watts 1989: 142, 341–42; Taylor 1993: 104–5; Peden 2000: 485–86; and Allen 2014: 144. Backhouse and Forder (2013: 20–23) provide an account of the evolution of the council’s doctrine from the First Report of February 1958 to the Fourth Report of July 1961, but they do not attempt to give any account of the institutional history of the council, nor do they explain why the council’s doctrine changed along the way (more on this in sec. 2 below). More information about the history of the council is available in Jones 1987: 54–56 and Dorey [2009] 2016: 105–9, but like Backhouse and Forder 2013, these works fail to make any systematic use of the council’s unpublished papers.

7.

The papers produced by the council, the memoranda submitted to the council, and the minutes of council meetings, including the meetings with witnesses, are in file T 178. In addition, files T 199/707, T 199/708, and T 298/341 provide further information. It must be noted that, in a complete and more balanced reconstruction of the council’s history, based on these (and possibly other) sources, the space occupied by Phillips 1958 would be much smaller than in the present article—and this for several reasons, including the obvious one that Phillips 1958 eventually failed to exert any influence on the council reports.

8.

Created in 1939, the Economic Section had become a subdivision of the Treasury in 1953. On the Economic Section under Robert Hall and its integration in the Treasury, see Cairncross and Watts 1989: chaps. 9–10.

9.

For a more detailed account of the disagreement between Thorneycroft and Hall, see Cairncross and Watts 1989: 226–30. See also Peden 2000: 487.

10.

The minutes of this meeting are in the file T 178/10.

11.

Thorneycroft’s memorandum of September 7, 1957, is quoted in Holmans 1999: 179. On this document, see also Peden 2000: 490.

12.

On September 10, 1957, Hall had made the same point in his evidence before the Radcliffe Committee (see Radcliffe Minutes, Q. 1387 [n. 5 provides more bibliographic information]). On this occasion, however, Hall had provided no quantitative assessment of the level of unemployment that might correspond to full, but not over-full, employment. Connected to this is a further example of the blind spots that remain. On September 10, Hall announced a memorandum that the Treasury staff was about to deliver, which provided a quantitative assessment of the relationship between unemployment and inflation, but this document never materialized.

13.

One of these occasions was “Wage Inflation,” an address given on various occasions and in its final form to the Bank of England in 1957, now reproduced in Dennison and Presley 1992: 71–81. As further examples of Robertson’s views on inflation immediately before his appointment as the council economist, see also “The Credit Squeeze” (in Dennison and Presley 1992: 59–70) and the chapter titled “Creeping Inflation” in Robertson 1956: 116–28.

14.

See the note circulated by Roger Makins of February 25, 1959, in T 199/707.

15.

A rather enthusiastic note, drafted for circulation within the Treasury and dated July 24, 1961, stated that “it [the council’s Fourth Report] fits in very well with the Chancellor’s current thought on many points.” At this date, the chancellor was Selwyn Lloyd. The note is in T 298/341.

16.

The technique adopted in estimating the curve equation, in particular, has been described and discussed in numerous contributions, some of which are mentioned in the present section, which in itself has nothing to add to this literature. Rather, it builds on this literature to emphasize the kinds of issues that, although frequently discussed in the scholarship on Phillips 1958 from Lipsey 1960 to the present day, barely emerged during the council seminars or even in published reactions to Phillips 1958 such as Dow et al. 1959, MacDougal 1959, Knowles and Winsten 1959, and Routh 1959 (more on this below in this section and in sec. 4).

17.

The third and fourth columns are not reproduced in table 1.

18.

On this, see also Hoover 2017.

19.

The relationship between Phillips 1954 and Phillips 1957, on the one hand, and Phillips 1958, on the other, has long been debated. For Laidler (2001: 7), “It is . . . a myth that the Phillips curve was a purely empirical relationship, devoid of theoretical foundations.” Forder (2014: 14–16), by contrast, sides with Gilbert (1976) against Desai (1975), follows Wulwick (1989) in considering Phillips’s method in deriving the curve as the application of rough-and-ready methods that were largely used at the time, and sees no theoretical link connecting the curve paper to Phillips’s works on stabilization (see also Forder 2019a: 592). The relevant point here is that how to relate Phillips 1958 to Phillips’s broader research agenda and how to evaluate the econometrics of the curve are questions that emerged at a later stage, and they certainly did not emerge in Phelps Brown’s council paper about Phillips and in the council seminars considered in sec. 4 below.

20.

Other comments of the same kind are reported in Forder 2014: 13. While Bollard (2016: 166) confirms that the paper was in fact a rush job, Hoover (2017) seems to attribute Phillips’s remarks to his self-deprecating character rather than to the intrinsic value of the curve paper.

21.

I wish to thank an anonymous referee for drawing my attention to this point.

22.

That Phillips’s results may have been obtained by pure chance is indirectly suggested by Dow et al. (1959: 18). In a brief comment on Phillips 1958, these authors observed that “the upper end of Professor Phillips’s curve fits surprisingly well to post-war data.” However, they also noted that the results were based on data for 1861–1913, and they concluded that “for a variety of reasons . . . it is doubtful how far the conclusions can be applied to present conditions.”

23.

Rather than ignoring the social, political, and institutional innovations that had been introduced since 1861, Phillips (1958) was denying that these changes had had any effect on the relationship between unemployment and wage inflation. As Forder (2014: 21–22) has argued, “The crucial thing was that if Phillips were correct . . . none of the political, social, institutional, or technological change brought by two world wars, the creation of the welfare state, the spread of unionism, and the universal franchise would have an effect [on wages].” That this was scarcely plausible is implicitly admitted in Phillips 1962. But it still remains that Phillips (1958) was denying the relevance, not ignoring the existence, of the noneconomic factors.

24.

The minutes of these meetings are in the file T 178/14. Unless otherwise stated, all quotations reported in this section are from this file. As explained in more detail below, it has not been possible to ascertain whether the contents of Council paper n. 126 and of Paper 3 circulated before the meetings with economists were exactly the same.

25.

In this way, Phelps Brown bypassed, without mentioning it, the objection made by Routh (1959), and also by Knowles and Winsten (1959), that Phillips had considered wage rates instead of earnings, thus ignoring the wage drift.

26.

The list of participants at this meeting includes Sir Sidney Caine, Frank Paish, Ely Devons, A. W. Phillips, H. B. Rose, Nancy Seear, B. C. Roberts, R. G. Lipsey, and A. C. L. Day.

27.

Of course, there is no way to be sure that the report of the meeting is altogether complete. So, it may be true that the link was made even though it does not show in the report.

28.

The title of Council paper n. 126 is “Notes on Causes of the Movement of Money Wages in Recent Years,” while the record of the meetings reports the title of Paper 3 as “Causes of the Movement of Money Wages in Recent Years.” But even though the two papers may have been almost identical, it seems plausible that the copy of the council paper that remained in the Treasury files was a preliminary draft of Paper 3 transmitted to the economists before the meetings.

29.

This indirectly confirms that, even if Council paper n. 126 and Paper 3 mentioned in the records of the meetings were not the same paper, their contents were not dissimilar.

References

Allen, William A.
2014
.
Monetary Policy and Financial Repression in Britain, 1951–59
.
London
:
Palgrave Macmillan
.
Backhouse, Roger, and James Forder.
2013
. “
Rationalizing Incomes Policy in Britain, 1948–1979
.”
History of Economic Thought and Policy
1
:
17
35
.
Blackaby, F. T.
1976
. “
The Target Rate of Unemployment
.” In
The Concept and Measurement of Involuntary Unemployment
, edited by G. D. N. Worswick,
279
304
.
London
:
Allen & Unwin
.
Bollard, Alan E.
2016
.
A Few Hares to Chase: The Economic Life and Times of Bill Phillips
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
.
Brittan, Samuel.
1964
.
The Treasury under the Tories, 1951–1964
.
Harmondsworth
:
Penguin Books
.
Brown, Arthur James.
1955
.
The Great Inflation, 1939–1951
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
.
Brown, Arthur James.
2000
.
Foreword to A. W. H. Phillips: Collected Works in Contemporary Perspective
, edited by R. Leeson,
xii
xv
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Cairncross, Alec, and Nita Watts.
1989
.
The Economic Section, 1939–1961: A Study in Economic Advising
.
London
:
Routledge
.
Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes
.
1958a
.
First Report
.
London
:
HMSO
.
Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes
.
1958b
.
Second Report
.
London
:
HMSO
.
Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes
.
1959
.
Third Report
.
London
:
HMSO
.
Council on Prices, Productivity, and Incomes
.
1961
.
Fourth Report
.
London
:
HMSO
.
Cristiano, C., and P. Paesani.
2018a
. “
Monetary Policy and Price Stability in British Post-war Debate: Restatement of Evidence from Economists' Papers Presented to the Radcliffe Committee
.”
European Journal of the History of Economic Thought
25
, no.
6
:
1311
41
.
Cristiano, C., and P. Paesani.
2018b
. “
Price Stability and the Origins and Early Influence of the Phillips Curve on British Policy Debates
.”
History of Political Economy
50
, no.
3
:
483
509
.
de Marchi, Neil.
1988
. “
Popper and the LSE Economists
.” In
The Popperian Legacy in Economics
, edited by Neil de Marchi,
139
66
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Dennison, S. R., and John R. Presley, eds.
1992
.
Robertson on Economic Policy
.
New York
:
St. Martin's Press
.
Desai, Meghnad.
1975
. “
The Phillips Curve: A Revisionist Interpretation
.”
Economica
, n.s.,
42
, no.
165
:
1
19
.
Dicks-Mireaux, L. A., and J. C. R. Dow.
1959
. “
The Determinants of Wage Inflation: United Kingdom, 1946–56
.”
Journal of the Royal Statistical Society
,
ser. A (General)
,
122
, no.
2
:
145
84
.
Dorey, Peter. (2009)
2016
.
British Conservatism and Trade Unionism, 1945–1964
.
London
:
Routledge
.
Dow, J. C. R.
1964
.
The Management of the British Economy, 1945–60
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Dow, J. C. R., L. A. Dicks-Mireaux, G. G. C. Routh, and B. M. Swift.
1959
. “
Price Stability and the Policy of Deflation
.”
National Institute Economic Review
3
:
16
29
.
Fellner, W., M. Gilberts, B. Hansen, R. F. Kahn, F. Lutz, and P. de Wolff.
1961
.
The Problem of Rising Prices
.
Paris
:
Organisation for European Economic Co-operation
.
Forder, James
2014
.
Macroeconomics and the Phillips Curve Myth
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
.
Forder, James.
2018
. “
A Response to David Laidler's Review of Macroeconomics and the Phillips Curve Myth
.” History of Economic Thought Society (website). https://thets.org.uk/book-reviews/a-response-to-david-laidlers-review-of-macroeconomics-and-the-phillips-curve-myth/.
Forder, James.
2019a
. “
A.W.H. Phillips (1914–1975)
.” In
The Palgrave Companion to LSE Economics
, edited by Robert A. Cord,
579
613
.
London
:
Palgrave Macmillan
.
Forder, James.
2019b
. “
The Phillips Curve
.” In
The Elgar Companion to John Maynard Keynes
, edited by Robert W. Dimand and Harald Hagemann,
554
59
.
Cheltenham
:
Edward Elgar
.
Gilbert, C. L.
1976
. “
The Original Phillips Curve Estimates
.”
Economica
43
, no.
169
:
51
57
.
Goodwin, R. M.
1967
. “
A Growth Cycle
.” In
Socialism, Capitalism, and Economic Growth
, edited by C. H. Feinstein,
54
58
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Hague, D. C., ed.
1962
.
Inflation: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association
.
London
:
Macmillan
;
New York
:
St. Martin's Press
.
Holmans, A. E.
1999
.
Demand Management in Britain, 1953–58
.
London
:
Institute of Contemporary British History
.
Holt, Charles C.
2000
. “
Interactions with a Fellow Research Engineer-Economist
.” In
A. W. H. Phillips: Collected Works in Contemporary Perspective
, edited by R. Leeson,
308
14
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Hoover, Kevin D.
2017
.
Review of A Few Hares to Chase: The Economic Life and Times of Bill Phillips
, by Alan Bollard.
Economic History Association
(website). http://eh.net/book_reviews/a-few-hares-to-chase-the-economic-life-and-times-of-bill-phillips/.
Hutchison, Terence Wilmot.
1967
.
Economics and Economic Policy in Britain, 1946–1966
.
London
:
Allen & Unwin
.
Jones, Kit.
1994
.
An Economist among Mandarins: A Biography of Robert Hall, 1901–1988
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Jones, Russell.
1987
.
Wages and Employment Policy, 1936–1985
.
London
:
Allen & Unwin
.
Klein, L. R., and R. J. Ball.
1959
. “
Some Econometrics of the Determination of Absolute Prices and Wages
.”
Economic Journal
69
, no.
275
:
465
82
.
Klein, L. R., R. J. Ball, and A. Hazlewood.
1959
. “
Econometric Forecasts for 1952
.”
Bulletin of the Oxford Institute of Statistics
21
, no.
1
:
3
16
.
Klein, L. R., et al
1961
.
An Econometric Model of the United Kingdom
.
Oxford
:
Blackwell
.
Knowles, K. G. J. C.
1962
. “
Wages and Productivity
.” In
The British Economy in the Nineteen-Fifties
, edited by G. D. N. Worswick and P. H. Ady,
502
36
.
Oxford
:
Clarendon
.
Knowles, K. G. J. C., and C. B. Winsten.
1959
. “
Can the Level of Unemployment Explain Changes in Wages?
Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics
21
, no.
2
:
113
20
.
Laidler, David.
1989
. “
Radcliffe, the Quantity Theory, and Monetarism
.” In
Money, Trade, and Payments
, edited by D. Cobham, R. Harrington, and G. Zis,
17
37
.
Manchester
:
Manchester University Press
.
Laidler, David.
2001
. “
Phillips in Retrospect
.” UWO Department of Economics Working Paper 20013. https://economics.uwo.ca/people/laidler_docs/phillips.pdf.
Laidler, David.
2014
.
Review of Macroeconomics and the Phillips Curve Myth
, by James Forder. History of Economic Thought Society (website). https://thets.org.uk/book-reviews/david-laidler-on-james-forders-macroeconomics-and-the-phillips-curve-myth-oup-2014/.
Lipsey, Richard G.
1960
. “
The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1862–1957: A Further Analysis
.”
Economica
, n.s.,
27
, no.
105
:
1
31
.
Lipsey, Richard G.
1962
. “
Can There Be a Valid Theory of Wages?
Advancement of Science
19
:
105
12
.
Lipsey, Richard G.
1978
. “
The Place of the Phillips Curve in Macroeconomic Models
.” In
Stability and Inflation
, edited by A. R. Bergstrom et al,
49
76
.
Chichester
:
John Wiley and Sons
.
Lipsey, Richard G.
2000
. “
The Famous Phillips Curve Article
.” In
A. W. H. Phillips: Collected Works in Contemporary Perspective
, edited by R. Leeson,
232
42
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Lipsey, Richard G.
2020
. “
Who's Who and What's What at the LSE, Then and Now? A Review Essay of The Palgrave Companion to LSE Economics
.” http://www.sfu.ca/repec-econ/sfu/sfudps/dp20-05.pdf.
MacDougall, G. D. A.
1959
. “
Inflation in the United Kingdom
.”
Economic Record
35
, no.
72
:
371
88
.
Paish, Frank W.
1958
. “
Inflation in the United Kingdom, 1948–57
.”
Economica
25
, no.
98
:
94
105
.
Paish, Frank W.
1962
.
Studies in an Inflationary Economy
.
London
:
Macmillan
.
Peden, George C.
2000
.
The Treasury and British Public Policy, 1906–1959
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
.
Phelps Brown, Henry E.
1958
. “
The Conditions for the Avoidance of the Spiral
.”
Scottish Journal of Political Economy
5
, no.
2
:
145
48
.
Phillips, Alban W. H.
1954
. “
Stabilisation Policy in a Closed Economy
.”
Economic Journal
64
, no.
254
:
290
323
.
Phillips, Alban W. H.
1957
. “
Stabilisation Policy and the Time-Forms of Lagged Responses
.”
Economic Journal
67
, no.
266
:
265
77
.
Phillips, Alban W. H.
1958
. “
The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957
.”
Economica
25
, no.
100
:
283
99
.
Phillips, Alban W. H. (1959)
2000
. “
Wage Changes and Unemployment in Australia, 1947–1958
.” In
A. W. H. Phillips: Collected Works in Contemporary Perspective
, edited by Robert Leeson,
269
81
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.
Phillips, Alban W. H.
1962
. “
Employment, Inflation, and Growth
.”
Economica
29
, no.
113
:
1
16
.
Robbins, Lionel.
1932
.
An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science
.
London
:
Macmillan
.
Robertson, Dennis Holme.
1956
.
Economic Commentaries
.
London
:
Staples Press
.
Routh, Guy.
1959
. “
The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates: A Comment
.”
Economica
26
, no.
104
:
299
315
.
Taylor, Robert.
1993
.
The Trade Union Question in British Politics
.
Oxford
:
Blackwell
.
Thomas, Jim.
2009
. “
Robbins's Nature and Significance and the M2T Seminar: Measurement with Theory and Theory with Measurement
.” In
Lionel Robbins's “Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science”: 75th Anniversary Conference Proceedings
, edited by Frank Cowell and Amos Witztum,
403
30
.
London
:
Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines
. http://darp.lse.ac.uk/papersdb/LionelRobbinsConferenceProveedingsVolume.pdf.
Wulwick, Nancy J.
1989
. “
Phillips' Approximate Regression
.”
Oxford Economic Papers
, n.s.,
41
, no.
1
:
170
88
.