Abstract
HIV risks decline sharply at age 30 for women in South Africa, long before coital frequencies or pregnancies decrease. I evaluate several prominent behavioral models of HIV, and find that these do not suggest sharply decreasing risks with age. I formulate a model of spousal search and find that “marital shopping” can generate epidemic HIV prevalence despite low transmission rates because search behavior interacts with dynamics of HIV infectiousness. The implied age-infection profile closely mimics that in South Africa, and the suggested behavior matches that reported by South Africans. Condom use in new relationships and transmission rate reductions are both found to be effective policies and, when used together, eliminate the potential of spousal search to spread HIV. In contrast, antiretroviral treatment is found to have only a minimal effect on the epidemic.
Introduction
A well-established consensus within the medical literature indicates that the average transmission rate of HIV is extremely low, on the order of 1 in 1,000 per sex act (e.g., Fideli et al. 2001; Gray et al. 2001; Quinn et al. 2000), or 8%–12% per partner-year. Despite this, antenatal prevalence is 40% in Botswana and 25% in South Africa, suggesting that many have been afflicted by this extremely unlikely event. Unsurprisingly, social scientists, epidemiologists, and the popular press have each weighed in on what sorts of behavior could yield such an outcome, with behavioral explanations ranging from heterogeneous preferences for risk (Kremer 1996) to networks of concurrent sexual partners (Morris and Kretzschmar 1997) to unfaithful husbands (Kristof 2005). An implicit criterion in evaluating each of these models is that high HIV prevalence can be obtained despite low transmission rates.
In this article, I ask which of these explanations could explain a majority of infections, and propose that the age-profile of infection represents a second useful criterion in assessing behavioral models of HIV. Death registries in South Africa reveal a strong age trend: HIV infection risk declines sharply after age 30 for women (and after age 35 for men). I open this article by discussing the age profile of infection, and illustrate that this decline in risk occurs too early in life to be explained simply by changing preferences with age, at least if these preferences are correlated with reported coital frequencies or pregnancy rates. I then argue that we can parse most existing behavioral HIV models into those that predict increasing risks with age and those that suggest age-independence (although a spurious decline with age may be generated by the absorbing nature of HIV infection). Intuitively, the sharp decline in risk levels with age seems unlikely to be generated by behavior for which risk is age-independent or age-increasing; as a formal test, I calibrate a flexible model of age-independent heterogeneous risk and find that this class of models does not fit the age-death profile in South Africa well, suggesting that age-independent models do not explain how most people contract HIV.1 Because these models dominate age-increasing risk in terms of fitting the observed age profile of HIV infection, rejecting age-independent models rules out this latter class of models as well.
Instead, the age-death profile prefers a model of decreasing risk, with risks of new infection declining at around age 30 for women (shortly after the median age of first marriage). This age profile, combined with an empirical trend that longer marital tenures are associated with reduced infection risks, suggests that the process of becoming married may be dangerous. This article is the first to show that a simple search and matching model of serial monogamy is capable of generating high prevalence with relatively few partners because short periods of high partner turnover coincide with a brief window of high infectiousness immediately following infection. That is, epidemic AIDS is possible even when the majority of individuals do not engage in high-risk behaviors. I then argue that a matching model of spousal search fits three additional empirical trends in the data. First, the model generates an age-death profile fitting that observed in South Africa across the duration of the epidemic well for both women and men—a close fit that is robust to a large variety of parametric assumptions. Second, the model closely predicts both the level and intertemporal variation in the annual number of partners that young adults report. Third, it suggests that spending a long time single should be associated with risk, but that the correlation between premarital sexual behavior and HIV should be eliminated for women who have been married for several years, a trend that is confirmed empirically across Africa. Finally, I evaluate the public health implications of “marital shopping” as an important vector for the spread of HIV by examining policies of transmission rate reductions, short-term condom usage, and antiretroviral (ARV) treatment. Short-term condom use is found to be the most effective of these strategies, and it eliminates the potential of spousal search to create an HIV epidemic when combined with the lower transmission rates found in the United States and Europe.
HIV in South Africa
Much of the data that could be used to learn about covariates of HIV infection is suspect. Antenatal prevalence data is subject to selection bias, population survey data often have high refusal rates, and cause of death statistics may be rigged. Changes in overall death rates in areas where the epidemic hit suddenly and recently, however, are immune to these concerns. Figure 1 presents deaths by age and gender observed in South Africa, where death registration is relatively complete (Dorrington et al. 2001; Statistics South Africa 2005). Epidemic AIDS is a recent phenomenon in South Africa, where antenatal prevalence was about 1% in 1990 (RSA 2008; U.S. Census Bureau 2006). This is reflected in the bottom line of each panel of the figure, which shows a relatively flat deaths-by-age profile in 1996. The top line, in contrast, tells a different story. By 2002, the number of 30- to 40-year-old women who died had more than tripled in six years. There is a much slighter increase in deaths for 40- to 45-year-old women; and by age 50, the death rate looks very similar to the historical one. For men, the age-death profile also peaks, although this happens five years later and the decline is less sharp. If we knew the precise time path of prevalence in South Africa, we could infer at precisely which age infection risk peaks. We don’t; however, an approximation can be found by subtracting 10 years from the death rates, given that individuals survive, on average, about 10 years after infection. This approximation suggests that women are at greatly reduced risks of infection after age 30.2
Epidemiological Models of HIV and Age
The fact that women in South Africa face risks that decline quickly with age could be driven by several factors that are unrelated to spousal search. First, this correlation could be driven by some biological factor of HIV transmission that is correlated with age. Second, it could be a consequence of changes in sexual risk that take place as adults age. Third, it could be the direct outcome of an existing behavioral epidemiological model.
Biological Correlates of Age
For the age trend in infection observed in South Africa to be a suitable criterion to evaluate behavioral models, it must not be determined by a biological component. Other sexually transmitted infections (STIs) increase the transmission risk of HIV (e.g., Oster 2005), which may have age implications. In fact, the observation that young people are far more likely to contract sexually transmitted disease is not unique to HIV nor to Africa. Whether gonorrhea or chlamydia in the United States (CDC 2005), human papilloma virus (HPV) in Costa Rica (Castle et al. 2005), or herpes simplex virus type 2 (HSV-2) throughout the world (Smith and Robinson 2002), the young are consistently the population who contract sexually transmitted diseases (STDs). Despite this observation, the presence of other STDs actually suggests an age-increasing risk profile for HIV infection. There is mixed evidence on whether non-ulcerative STDs affect HIV transmission at all, and it is widely believed that ulcerative STDs play a much larger role (e.g., Fleming and Wasserheit 1999). The most prevalent ulcerative STD in Africa and the world is HSV-2 (e.g., Chen et al. 2000; Wawer et al. 1999). Therefore, the HIV risks that are induced by other STDs should follow the age profile of HSV-2. Because HSV-2 is incurable and nonfatal, the highest prevalence is among the old, as documented empirically across Africa in Smith and Robinson (2002). Thus, STDs as risk factors suggest that older men and women should be at an elevated risk of HIV infection, not a much lower one.
Age-Changing Preferences
A second possibility is that this age trend is an immediate outcome of age-changing preferences about coital frequencies. Although 30 seems a very young age for a sharp decrease in preferences about coital frequency, two forms of evidence are available to evaluate this possibility, both available in the 1998 South African Demographic and Health Survey (DHS). The first is self-reported sexual behavior, which is presented in Panel A of Table 1. For all potential coital frequencies, we see reported sexual behavior increasing until age 40, after which it remains higher than the reported behavior of women in their 20s, which are the ages that the death profile tells us involve peak HIV risk.
However, sexual behavior data is notoriously difficult to measure, and women in particular have been shown to misreport badly (Gersovitz et al. 1998). Therefore, we may be concerned that these differences simply reflect differences in reporting bias, and pregnancy may be preferred as a biomarker. Panel B of Table 1 reports pregnancy rates by age. Indeed, pregnancy rates decline after age 30, as reported in column 1. However, natural declines in fecundity also begin around age 30 (Te Velde and Pearson 2002). Table 1 shows births per year divided by the probability of conception for that age found in two studies: Templeton et al. (1996) and van Noord-Zaadstra et al. (1991).3 As Panel B of Table 1 shows, the actual births per year fall between what the two estimates would predict if sexual behavior remained constant, at least for women younger than 40. These data do not support the hypothesis that women’s age-specific preferences about coital frequency are insulating them from their husbands’ behavior at older ages, nor that women begin to prefer lower coital frequencies at an early age.4
Existing Behavioral Epidemiological Models of HIV
Because average HIV infectiousness is so low, models that achieve high HIV prevalence with feasible amounts of sexual behavior often rely on fundamental heterogeneity between individuals. The class of models that has dominated the economics literature revolves around individuals having heterogeneous preferences of sexual risk or variety (e.g., Kremer 1996; Philipson and Posner 1993). In Kremer’s specification, heterogeneous individuals optimize a rate of partner change. A high-risk group seeks out many partners, lower-risk individuals occasionally search for new partners, and partnerships form at random. High-risk individuals are overrepresented in the pool of available partners because of their greater frequency of partner search, increasing the chances of drawing a partner with above population-average risk.
This model belongs to the class of age-independent risk models. Although different individuals prefer different risk levels and some may be likely to become infected earlier in life than others, any uninfected individual will face an identical probability of infection in each period that she remains uninfected. Another age-independent model emphasizes sexual networks of concurrent partners (Morris and Kretzschmar 1997). After HIV is introduced to a network, it can spread quickly throughout the network, exposing all members to high risk. As such, all members of a network are exposed to very similar risk levels, regardless of age. Presumably, individuals are heterogeneous with respect to the size and turnover rate of their networks, so we may expect this model to produce very similar age predictions to the preference-based model.5
Can an age-independent risk model with heterogeneous types generate an age-death profile like that of South Africa? In principle, a two-type model might: high-risk types become quickly infected and die out while still young, while low-risk types remain safe. However, this sort of explanation makes two extreme assumptions. First, there are no middle-risk types, who likely survive their youth and continue to be stochastically infected later in life; second, the epidemic is in its steady state. Self-reports of the number of sexual partners in the last year from 14- to 22-year-olds in South Africa, although subject to the concerns discussed in the previous section, seem to contradict the first assumption. As reported in columns 2 and 4 of Table 2, young adults in South Africa report a triangular distribution of annual partners, with the majority being low risk. More importantly, epidemic stability is necessary because this age-independent explanation revolves around the high-risk older women having already attrited from the population, which would not have happened at the onset of the epidemic (as in the case of South Africa).
Age-Independent Model Calibration
Figure 2 shows that a 35-year-old epidemic can fit the age-death profile quite well: the intuition holds that if everyone at risk is at high risk, the risky die while young, leaving behind low-risk people who will reach old age. However, in the early stages of the infection, a heterogeneous-risk model cannot fit the profile. In fact, around year 15, the highest risk is among the oldest groups, in contrast to what we observe in the data. In other words, if people belong to one of three risk types, and those risk types remain relatively constant over lifetimes, then no matter how much risk each of those types contain, or what fraction of the population belongs to each of those types, we should observe far more older people being infected in early-stage epidemics than we actually observe in South Africa. The reason for this is simple and is not driven by the stylized assumptions that make this calibration tractable: at the onset of an epidemic, older individuals of all risk levels are being exposed for the first time. Therefore, if risks are independent of age, the first cohort exposed includes risky people of all ages and should feature deaths at all age groups. In South Africa, the epidemic is simply too new for an age-independent risk model to be a strong candidate explanation for most infections.
Marriage as a Risk Factor
Given that age-independent models of heterogeneous risk are unable to generate South Africa’s decline in risk with age, we can be certain that age-increasing models are poor approximations to the behaviors by which most people contract HIV. As argued earlier, this suggests that the presence of other sexually transmitted diseases do not serve as a stand-alone story for the age-death profile in South Africa. Another theory that suggests age-increasing risks is the possibility that men bring HIV risk into marriage through extramarital affairs. Kristof (2005) argued this case, writing that, “The stark reality is that what kills young women [in Africa] is not promiscuity, but marriage. Indeed, just about the deadliest thing a woman in Southern Africa can do is get married.” However, because older (and, more often, married) women are even safer in South Africa than they would be if marriage had a neutral effect on risk, we can rule out the “cheating husbands” theory as being the explanation for most women becoming infected.
This theory is so pervasive that it is worth reviewing the evidence that has led to it. Clearly, some risk is associated with a long-term partnership, for both men and women (De Walque 2007). However, a lack of long-run panel data, combined with mortality-related attrition and low HIV transmission rates, has left us without a good sense of how that risk compares with the risks of premarital behaviors. Much of the evidence on extramarital risk has come through anecdotal and ethnographic channels, which are hard-pressed to answer questions of relative magnitudes. Even if a large fraction of adults have extramarital partners, risks may be low if the existence of a spouse prevents high-frequency sex with these partners. Empirical evidence on marital risk has been mixed, with Clark (2004) finding that married teenage girls have higher prevalence than their unmarried peers and concluding that marriage is risky. In contrast, Bongaarts (2006) found that marriage is less risky than being sexually active and single, and Glynn et al. (2001) documented that married women who avoided premarital sex have lower prevalence of HIV than their married peers who did not.
The idea that married women may have higher HIV prevalence than unmarried women is consistent with the idea that a year of marriage might be less risky than a year of being sexually active and single if the process of becoming married is dangerous yet staying married is relatively safe. Individual-level data with HIV status are not publicly available for South Africa, preventing a direct examination of this hypothesis. However, in all the high-prevalence countries with publicly available DHS data including serostatus, suggestive evidence exists that it is indeed the process of becoming married that garners risk. If becoming married carries much risk, then we should observe surviving couples being more likely to test jointly negative if they have been married for long enough that preexisting infections should have resulted in death. In Online Resource 1, I show that monogamous couples who have been married for at least 10 years are substantially (and statistically significantly in every DHS country available, save Lesotho) more likely to test jointly negative than couples who have been married 0–5 years. This trend is robust to flexible age and spousal age controls and in some cases, represents truly substantial risk reductions. Across Africa, there is evidence that the process of becoming married, but not being married, is risky.
Spousal Search
The process that leads to marriage has changed substantially in sub-Saharan Africa over the past 50 years, just as it has elsewhere in the developing world. A large body of research has emphasized globally that traditional, kinship-based marital institutions are being replaced by Western notions of courtship, wherein individuals must identify for themselves suitable partners to marry (e.g., Ghimire et al. 2006 and Thornton et al. 1994; for African examples, see Mukiza-Gapere and Ntozi 1995; and also Smith 2000). Recent research has more directly emphasized the parallels between Western notions of courtship and premarital behaviors in Africa, where researchers have documented that young people engage in sexual relationships as part of a search for long-term monogamous relationships with psychologically compatible partners (Clark et al. 2010) and that the likelihood of marriage is important in the choice of sexual behavior among premarital partners (Clark et al. 2009).7
Model




To solve this model, individuals solve backward. In the penultimate period, each person faces a choice between staying with her current partner (for whom θij is known, and can be predicted with some accuracy) or finding a new one. Therefore, she stays with the current relationship if
or if her current relationship is better in expected value than she might expect to do by drawing a new one. Otherwise, she ends her current relationship and finds a new partner, indexed j′, from whom she receives match-specific utility
in her last period of life. The previous period, the choice is slightly more complicated; here, she stays if the expected value of the current relationship—including the option value of being able to end that relationship in the following period—is larger than the expected value of a new relationship, again considering the possibility that that relationship could be terminated after one period. Iterating back to the first period leads to the well-known solution for search models, wherein optimal behavior is to form a sequence of reservation qualities,
, where individuals stay in any relationship where
. In this specification,
so that as individuals age, reservation qualities lower. This means that the probability of a good relationship turning sour enough to dissolve after a certain age becomes low, creating “marriage” behavior. In my preferred specification, match evolution is slow, so that the first period provides a fairly accurate measure of the quality of a relationship; this evolution rate creates behavior that mimics the observed nine-year time span from sexual initiation until marriage in South Africa. This evolution can be interpreted as truly evolving utility from a partner or as a learning process. In any matching model, a large fraction of relationships are rejected immediately because reservation qualities are always bounded below by the expectation of the quality of a new match. As a result, individuals have clusters of several short relationships in between a few much longer ones; this will have disastrous consequences for the HIV epidemic. I define marriage as occurring at the date when a person begins to match with her (ex post) last partner. Men and women match randomly with someone else who is actively searching for a new partner. After 20 years, individuals quit searching, with a payoff of 10 years’ worth of utility at the current match quality.9 Men and women are identical in this model; this assumption is supported by de Walque (2007), who observed that in a large fraction of couples, only one is infected, equally often the woman as the man.
Integrating HIV Into the Matching Model
The average rate of infection per partnership-year (PPY) has been documented through longitudinal studies in Uganda and Zambia. By following serodiscordant couples (in which only one member is HIV positive) through time, medical researchers observe transmission rates. The studies in Rakai, Uganda, are particularly compelling because their participants report minimal condom use despite counseling. These studies estimate average infection rates of about 12% PPY (Gray et al. 2001; Quinn et al. 2000), which corresponds to an infection rate per contact of approximately 1 in 1,000. Transmission in Lusaka, Zambia, where higher condom use was reported, was lower at 8% PPY (Fideli et al. 2001).
However, the average infection rate may not be a sufficient statistic to understand the dynamics of HIV transmission. PPY rates do not describe within-individual or between-individual heterogeneity in infectiousness, and there is substantial evidence that both are important for HIV. Many studies (e.g., Gray et al. 2001; Pedraza et al. 1999; Quinn et al. 2000) have documented the correlation between viral load and infectiousness. In terms of viral load, we can divide a person’s HIV infection into three broad periods. First, acute infection lasts for the first two to three months, during which the body has not developed an immune response to HIV and viral load is high. In this period, HIV may be 10 times as infectious as it will be later (Pilcher et al. 2004; Wawer et al. 2005). Next, in latent infection (the next eight years or so), the body’s immune response keeps viral load extremely low. Finally, the body’s immune system starts to fail at containing the virus, and the infection becomes mature. Starting about two years before death, viral loads begin climbing. As viral loads increase, AIDS breaks out, causing death within about one year without medical intervention (e.g., Katzenstein 2003). People in the longitudinal studies described earlier are primarily in the second phase of infection, which is why low average transmission rates are consistently observed. In the epidemiological model most similar to this one, Koopman et al. (1997) assumed that individuals transition randomly between high- and low-turnover states and match nonrandomly with others in the same state. Considering infection among homosexuals in the United States, and assuming very risky behavior, they found that shutting down acute infection may end the epidemic entirely.10
Therefore, it is important to take into account the dynamics of HIV infection. I specify that if an individual of gender g matches with a partner who is in phase k of infection, that person faces probability of infection. After becoming infected, individuals die according to the survival function published in UNAIDS (2004). Two years before death, individuals enter mature infection (following Wawer et al. 2005). I do not allow individuals whose partners have died from HIV to find a new match unless they would have resumed searching from the relationship’s evolution in any event. In each cohort, a small percentage (δ) enter already infected with HIV, with δ/6 entering in acute infection.11 This consistent injection of HIV can be interpreted as infection from all sexual behaviors other than spousal search. Individuals who are initially infected do not behave differently from other individuals.
Each period corresponds to one month. Latent transmission rates are those measured by Gray et al. (2001) for young couples (slightly above average rates owing to the greater coital frequency of young couples), whereas acute and mature transmission rates follow Pilcher et al. (2004) and Wawer et al. (2005).12 The distribution over θ is uniform and chosen for simplicity; changing to other simple distributions alters lifetime numbers of partners and HIV prevalence only slightly, since reservation qualities endogenously adjust downward when good matches become more scarce. Men and women are identical in this model, and as such, they have similar simulated data; I present only the results for simulated women.
Simulating the Model
To simulate this model, I first solve the dynamic programming problem numerically (distributional assumptions and summary statistics from the simulated data are given in Online Resource 1). Then, I simulate N men and N women in the first cohort, each of whom randomly draws a partner from the simulated opposite sex and receives a draw of partner quality. At the end of the period, each person decides whether to stay in their relationship or to draw a new one based on the solution of the dynamic programming problem. If both members choose to stay, the relationship match quality evolves, and each member faces the same decision in the subsequent period. If either member chooses to leave, both people receive a new partner from the pool of other individuals who choose to search and a new draw on θ. The outcome of this random process is that individuals stay single for about 8.5 years, which is close to South Africa’s empirical data. (The median South African woman becomes sexually active at 17 and married at 25.) Over the 20 years of sexual activity, the median person has 11 partners. Eleven partners over 20 years is low relative to many epidemiological models, which typically assume that individuals acquire at least 1–2 new partners per year (e.g., Actuarial Society of South Africa (ASSA) 2005; Morris and Kretzschmar 1997; Oster 2005) and sometimes assume many more (e.g., Koopman et al. 1997). Every 10 months, a new cohort of N individuals of each sex enters the pool of searching singles and similarly draws a partner and a match quality. I simulate the model for 40 years; I do not explicitly model homophily in age so that entering cohorts are treated the same as single individuals in existing cohorts (although, of course, their age is different, resulting in a different solution to the search problem). With the entry of the 10th cohort, the HIV epidemic begins, and all living individuals face instantaneous probability δ of contracting HIV.13 Following, each new cohort enters with prevalence δ, and HIV transmission occurs as HIV-negative partners of HIV-positive individuals face random draws against the transmission rate. The two sources of randomization in this model are the match process and the HIV epidemic. After the match has been solved, the spread of HIV happens in a way that is computationally quick. All results presented are for 50 realizations of the match, each averaged over 10 realizations of the epidemic.
Results
Table 3 reports the fraction of fully exposed women who will become infected for each δ. Marital shopping acts as a multiplier of 5–7 on inputted infections, so that each percentage point of inputted infections results in about 6% of people becoming infected. In other words, each person who enters the spousal search period infected will cause about 2 to 2.5 other single people to become infected, and all of them go on to infect the person they eventually marry. Thus, if 1% of the population enters the spousal search period infected, we end up with a prevalence rate similar to that in Kenya or Tanzania. With just 3% infected by all sexual behaviors other than spousal search, we are at South Africa’s epidemic prevalence rates. The reason for this is basic behavior generated by matching models (and hence fairly insensitive to parametric assumptions). Individuals have clusters of several very short relationships that are easily rejected in between a few much longer ones. Therefore, when they enter a new relationship, they are likely to have just left another very short one. In turn, this means that they are much more likely to have just been infected, will remain in the acute phase of infection, and hence are more likely to infect their new partner. Prevalence among the first six cohorts reaches 80% of its eventual peak (not presented here). Thus, with a tiny fraction of the population entering the spousal search phase of their lives infected, marital shopping can create an epidemic quickly.
To explore the importance of acute infection, Rows 3 and 4 of Table 3 report prevalence results if the acute infection transmission rate, ρ1 were 0. The results are strong: acute infection is responsible for a large fraction of the infections caused by spousal search, including about one-third of infections for δ < .05. Now, δ is multiplied by 4–5 rather than 5–7, so that each initially infected person causes only about 1 to 1.5 other infections before both people infect their spouses. This thought experiment is interesting for two reasons. First, it supports data from Switzerland (Yerly et al. 2001), which show that more than one-third of infections are attributable to acute infection, and Wawer et al. (2005) demonstrated similar results in Uganda. Second, it is implementable. A policy of wearing condoms for the first three months of each relationship would stop new infections caused by acute infection. While a preference for condoms in short relationships is familiar and intuitive, it represents a sharp divergence from the current message being spread by many non-governmental organizations (NGOs), which promote condom use throughout marriage (e.g., Ali et al. 2004). This policy is evaluated more explicitly later in this article.
Theoretical predictions and data can be used to determine the age profile of infection and death suggested by spousal search with minimal reliance on parametric assumptions. More specifically, matching models imply that infection risk is more or less constant for uninfected single individuals.14 Among married individuals, in contrast, it declines exponentially. Because no new infections are brought into a marriage, one’s risk at any point in time is the product of the transmission rate, the risk that one’s spouse entered the marriage already infected, the chance that one entered the marriage uninfected, and the probability that it hasn’t yet been contracted from one’s spouse. Similarly, the time path of risk suggests the relative fraction of infections occurring to single and married individuals. The algebraic identities suggested by these predictions are straightforward, if tedious, and are contained in Online Resource 1.
Using the South African DHS (South Africa Department of Health and ORC Macro 2001), I estimate Kaplan-Meier hazard functions into marriage and into sexual activity to estimate search and marriage behavior, with the assumption that being unmarried but having had sex is reflective of being single and searching.15 Because the DHS provides data only on women, I estimate the men’s hazard function into marriage by taking means by age of the fraction married from the September 2001 South African Labour Force Survey (Statistics South Africa 2002–2004), and I alternatively assume that the hazard function into sexual activity is the same for men as it is for women, or that it is shifted to five years older because South African men marry, on average, five years later than women. As described earlier, I know the risk profiles for single and married individuals if I know the time path of the epidemic and the relative prevalence rates for newlyweds and singles. Therefore, to construct the age-death profile, I need only the time paths of the prevalence for newlyweds and single people. These are taken from simulations; reassuringly, Figs. 3 and 4 are robust to reasonable changes in both single and married prevalence trends because it is the empirical distributions of singlehood and marriage as well as the theoretical risk predictions that produce the close fit.
Figure 3 presents this comparison. Here, I make the further assumption that the number of deaths by age in 1996 represents the number of non-AIDS deaths in 2002, and I set the peak of simulated AIDS deaths equal to the empirical peak. That is, the height of the curves is rigged; however, that is the only point that is expressly fit, and the shape of my predicted age-death curve is derived from the theory and the data. The fit is very close.16 I very slightly underpredict older women’s deaths. Because this model assumes perfect monogamy, extramarital sex may create this difference; however, the quantity of infections that this nonmonogamy produces is tiny in comparison with the number of monogamous infections. For men, the data lie between the age death curves created by assuming that men have the same sexual initiation as women and assuming that their sexual initiation is five years older. Still, the fit is overall very close and is distinguishable from the fit for women. Men marry five years later than women and over a broader range of ages, and that is precisely how they die.
There is no reason to expect that the marital shopping model would fit the epidemic only in 2002. Figure 4 estimates the model for every year from 1997 to 2002. For men, I take the average of the predicted results from the two assumptions on sexual initiation. For both men and women and at all years of the epidemic, I find a close fit (once again, only the peak of each year is fixed). Moreover, some of the time dynamics in the age profile of infection are preserved between the model and the data, not least being the age peak from early years, which was absent in the heterogeneous risk model. Regarding the female age-prevalence profile, at the onset of the epidemic, peak deaths occurred in the 25–30 age group, with a similar rate among 30- to 35-year-olds; by 2002, 30- to 35-year-olds experienced more deaths. This is predicted by the marital shopping model.
Marital Shopping or Preferences Over Variety?
In the marital shopping model, people are motivated by the utility payoff of finding a high-quality partner. They undergo search in their youth, which is characterized by brief periods of high partner turnover in between longer periods with a single monogamous partner. Ultimately, they find a high-quality match and they marry. A behaviorally similar model (and one that would generate an identical age-profile construction as that used earlier) would be that individuals prefer to have a high rate of partner turnover in their youth until they exogenously prefer to have a single partner at heterogeneous ages. It is doubtless true that both changing preferences about variety and the presence of a high-quality partner play a role in marriage decisions. A few distinctions are worth noting. First, spousal search generates higher HIV prevalence than a changing preference model with an identical number of partners. This follows because the short periods of high turnover are a major contributor to the potential of spousal search to spread HIV. If partner turnover is relatively uniformly distributed over time, this potential is attenuated. Further, if preferences about variety decline in a smooth and monotonic manner, then the predictions based on age are a worse fit than those created by a spousal search model. The spousal search model presumes that individuals are of constant risk over their ages of singlehood, and already fully explains the number of infections among the very young. Finally, as discussed later in this article, an implication of marital shopping (unlike preferences about variety) is that there should be a high variance in intertemporal choices in sexual partners, which is supported by self-reported sexual behavior data. However, it remains true that a model wherein individuals transition randomly between preferences for high and low rates of partner turnover and exogenously prefer a single partner after a particular age would be behaviorally equivalent to the one presented earlier and hence would have similar predictions.17 As with any model, this one is indistinguishable in data from behaviorally equivalent, exogenously changing preferences. However, many policy predictions remain similar in either case.
Spousal Search, Sexual Behavior, and Risk
In a spousal search, a large number of partners is simply an indication of bad luck in finding a good match in a given year rather than an indication of underlying preferences. Thus, if this model is relevant, we should observe relatively little serial correlation in number of partners. Moreover, most people will have isolated years when they have several partners, but most years will be spent with a single partner because most time is spent with either a long-term partner or with a spouse. Therefore, a second prediction of spousal search is that most of the time, nearly everyone has only a single partner in a given year.
As discussed earlier, sexual behavior data are problematic and known to be biased with strong underreporting. It is not clear whether bias changes over time, so it is not clear whether bias could itself account for a low level of serial correlation in the number of partners. The Cape Area Panel Study (CAPS) 18 (Lam et al. 2006), which is a random sample of 4,758 teens and young adults ages 14–22 in 2002 who live in the Cape Town Metropolitan Area, however, can provide suggestive evidence. Here, I examine the self-reports on the number of sexual partners from the previous 12 months for CAPS respondents who had sex at least once by 2002 and the same respondents three years later in 2005. I then compare the scatterplot of these respondents with that generated by 2,500 observations of simulated data. CAPS respondents are younger than a random selection of simulated adults from the model. Thus, I choose for each simulated observation one of the first five years at random to represent that simulated person’s behavior in 2002 and then compare the number of partners that observation had in that year with the same observation three years later. I then overlay the two scatterplots for easy comparison, weighting each observation so that the sample sizes are identical.
Figure 5 shows the results of this exercise. Here, simulated data are represented by diamonds, actual data are represented by squares, and the size of each point is proportional to the frequency with which it occurs in the data. One deviation from the model is that it does not allow individuals to transition out of sexual activity and a few individuals in CAPS have 0 partners in a year after they have had sex at least once. These observations aside, the fit is quite remarkable. In both CAPS and the simulated data, the overwhelming majority of observations have one partner in 2002, and again one partner three years later in 2005. Also, in both CAPS and the simulated data, substantial fractions have more than one partner in one of the two years; however, it is extremely infrequent to observe individuals who have many partners in both years. The overwhelming majority of individuals with several sexual partners in either one of the two years had only one partner in the other. This is striking, particularly because any models that rely on fundamental heterogeneity would suggest the opposite. That is, if some people simply prefer more variety, one would expect this preference to be serially correlated; however, in practice, reported behavior is not. I also impose a regression line for both simulated and actual data to describe the relationship between partners in 2002 and partners in 2005. The constant term is slightly larger in the simulated data; however, the estimated slopes are both indistinguishable from 0 and from each other. Teens and young adults in Cape Town report sexual behavior that is strikingly similar to that suggested by the marital shopping model.
The model of courtship and marriage developed here would seem appropriate for the United States and Europe, too, and so it would be reassuring if young adults in both contexts reported similar sexual behavior. Columns 1 and 3 of Table 2 report tabulations of numbers of partners in the past year among U.S. adolescents from the National Survey of Family Growth (NSFG; National Center for Health Statistics 2002); columns 2 and 4 report similar calculations for CAPS respondents (all data are described in Online Resource 1). Across cultures, the annual numbers of reported partners appear identical. To the extent that adolescent males are partnering only with adolescent females, we know that one of these two groups is misreporting. Strikingly, even the bias in male versus female reporting appears to be consistent between the two continents.19
Finally, if spousal search is dangerous, then those who spend a longer time single should be at greater risk of HIV infection. That is, a longer time period spent single indicates less luck in finding a match, and should be positively correlated with the amount of risk borne. Data to test this possibility are not available for South Africa; however, in Online Resource 1, I use DHS data to illustrate that length spent single is correlated with HIV status across Africa, and that it is correlated only for those who have been married recently enough to have survived whatever infections were suffered during their singlehood. That is, a long singlehood is strongly predictive of HIV status for people who have been married less than 10 years but not for individuals who have been married for more than 10 years. This suggests that high risk is created by long singlehood, rather than things like preferences, which may be correlated with singlehood but would persist into marriage. Although those who have been married longer may be an imperfect control group, this analysis represents additional suggestive evidence that spousal search is dangerous.
Policy Discussion
In this article, I consider three policies to reduce the spread of HIV. The first is for individuals to use condoms for the first three months of each relationship. The majority of relationships in this model are short in tenure because most partnerships are quickly found unacceptable; thus, using condoms at the beginning of relationships may prevent transmission from most lifetime partners and would eliminate the role of acute infection. I consider what happens when fraction λ of the population follows this policy. Panel A of Table 4 observes the mean lifetime prevalence across cohorts for a variety of λ, in each case assuming δ = .03, which relates to the South African epidemic.20 For each λ, the overall prevalence is reported and then decomposed into the prevalence for those who follow this strategy and the prevalence for those who do not. The strategy of wearing condoms in short relationships is very effective for those who follow it: in each case, inputted values of δ are multiplied by 3–4.5 for those who follow this strategy and 4–5.5 for those who do not. Strong evidence of externalities emerges; as some individuals protect themselves, epidemic progression is limited, and everyone faces lower risks. Moreover, if everyone uses protection in short relationships, epidemic prevalence falls tremendously: each new infection is responsible for about two additional infections. In a model like this, spouses will almost deterministically become infected, so that each inputted infection now causes about one-half of an additional couple to become infected (rather than 2–2.5 couples in the baseline case).
A second potential policy is to reduce the transmission rate of HIV, either through reducing the prevalence of STIs (e.g., Oster 2005) or through male circumcision (e.g., Potts et al. 2008). Using the marital shopping model, we can observe the effect of reducing transmission rates on prevalence while remaining agnostic about the best mechanism to achieve such a result. A review of medical studies (presented in Online Resource 1) suggests that transmission in the United States and Europe is on the order of 50%–100% as efficient as in Africa.21 I take the midpoint and assume that a 25% transmission rate reduction is accomplishable through biological means. The Western transmission rates rows of Table 4 repeat the marital shopping model but reduce transmission risks in all stages of infection to 75% of the previous levels. The first row indicates what can be expected if transmission rates are reduced by 25% without accompanying behavioral change. In this case, the multiplier changes from between 6 and 7 to just more than 4, or one extra couple being infected. Clearly, this is an effective strategy, about as effective as compelling one-half of individuals to use condoms in their short relationships; which of these approaches is more feasible is an empirical question.22 Table 4 also explores the consequences of reducing transmission rates in parallel with short-term condom use. The results here are strong. In this model, there is basically no way to reduce the multiplier below 2: individuals who enter spousal search already infected will very probably infect their eventual spouse. When the transmission rate is reduced to Western levels and individuals are compelled to use condoms in their short relationships, very few individuals other than spouses ever become infected. If Americans have these transmission rates and follow this strategy of protection in short relationships, it may explain why spousal search does not create an HIV epidemic in the United States despite otherwise similar sexual behavior. Strategies that seek to reduce transmission rates through treatment of sexually transmitted diseases and male circumcision can effectively combat the epidemic, as can short intervals of protected sex, and the pursuit of both strategies in tandem may be tremendously effective.
The third potential policy is ARV treatment for the epidemic. ARV treatment both extends life and reduces transmission rates, creating, in principle, an ambiguous effect on the epidemic and leading to mixed findings in the epidemiological literature (Cohen et al. 2007). Standard medical practice is to treat individuals either just before or at the onset of AIDS; hence, in calibrating, I assume that life is extended for three to seven years in between latent and mature infection, and transmission rates are reduced to between 0% and 50% of that latent infection rate.23 As Panel B of Table 4 illustrates, ARV treatment has only a limited effect on the epidemic, resulting in at most a 15% reduction in prevalence or potentially a very small increase. The reason for this is simple: by the time people are nearing the end of their HIV infection, they are typically married and no longer accumulating many new partnerships. This suggests that using ARVs to provide a similar window of low infectiousness earlier in the infection’s course may be much more effective, and similar simulations (not presented here) reveal that extending life by reducing infectiousness in the first years of infection may be associated with substantial reductions in epidemic prevalence.24 This heightens the immediacy of current medical studies, which are testing the value of treating HIV-positive individuals long before the onset of AIDS (HPTN 2010). It also highlights the importance of the underlying behavioral modeling: models that do not account for the life history of sexual risk would overstate epidemiological implications of current ARV practice.
Conclusions
Serial monogamy with high turnover is sufficient to create and maintain high prevalence levels and can inflate infection rates from other sources to much higher levels. Simple dating can create this behavior, if there are idiosyncratic, unpredictable components to the quality of a relationship and individuals prefer spending more time with better matches. In contrast with many existing behavioral models that can achieve high prevalence with low transmission rates, the matching model is consistent with the observed age-death profile. Moreover, matching also supports empirical evidence on the importance of acute infection for the HIV epidemic without requiring extremely high numbers of partners.
If individuals use protection in only their short relationships, prevalence rates fall dramatically, with 50% usage being as effective as a reduction in transmission rates to Western levels. This highlights an important choice for public policy: should policy makers emphasize using condoms in new relationships at the cost of using them in older ones? Some individuals may find three months of condom use more palatable than a lifetime of protection, and a tremendous amount of risk would be averted.25 Indeed, this message contrasts strongly with the message adopted by many public health groups, who encourage condom use throughout marriage. As many individuals doubtless hope to have unprotected sex at some point in their lives, it would be dangerous if they felt they had to make an all-or-nothing choice because they did not understand the relative risks of premarital and marital sex. Moreover, when short-term condom use is combined with reduced transmission rates, marital shopping ceases to be an effective mechanism to transmit HIV, suggesting two clear goals for policy. This also suggests that public health campaigns should target young and single men and women, with a message stressing the risks in new relationships.
An implication emerging from the medical literature is that testing campaigns will be hard to sell. Antibody-based tests are by far the cheapest and predominantly in use both in Africa and in the United States. However, these tests cannot detect acute infection because the body has not yet developed an immune response and therefore they misdiagnose HIV when it is most infectious. Because much of the risk that a person faces with a new partner is caused by acute infection, demanding that a partner get tested before intercourse is not fully protective. Moreover, if a negative result encourages choosing against condoms, then it could actually make sex more dangerous. This may pose a major challenge to testing initiatives.
Finally, I show in this article that serially monogamous dating and marriage behavior acts as a multiplier on low prevalence rates from outside sources, and simulated evidence suggests that spousal search could cause 5/6–6/7 of all infections. Another consequence of this multiplier is that small changes in the number of these outside infections can lead to huge differences in the prevalence rate. This article, as well as others (e.g., Oster 2005), has documented the similarity in reports of sexual behavior between Africa and the United States; it has also reemphasized how similar behavior with differences in transmission rates and short-term condom use can explain the different prevalence levels. However, a few pivotal people may well behave differently and become infected through other methods, and both the aggregate statistics that are central to this article and traditional econometric analysis are ill-suited to identifying these small samples, perhaps explaining the divergence between these results and the reports of ethnographers. Respondent-driven sampling methodologies (e.g., Heckathorn 1997) may be an asset in understanding the behavior of this pivotal minority.
Acknowledgments
I am indebted to Fabian Lange, Ethan Ligon, Ted Miguel, Nicoli Nattrass, Emily Oster, Rohini Pande, Claus Portner, Paul Schultz, Jeremy Seekings, Chris Udry, Damien de Walque; and seminar participants at Yale, Berkeley, Harvard, the University of Washington, and the University of Cape Town for many helpful suggestions. All mistakes are naturally my own.
Notes
Elements of these models may still have severe epidemiological consequences because variations in the behavior of a small fraction of individuals may cause huge swings in prevalence. I return to this point in the conclusion.
This trend is not unique to South Africa, nor is it a recent observation. Although good mortality records do not exist for other countries in sub-Saharan Africa, individual medical studies have revealed similar age-death profiles from HIV in Uganda (Sewankambo et al. 2000) and the Democratic Republic of Congo (Pictet et al. 1998). Anderson et al. (1991) provided an early documentation of this age pattern in an influential review. Despite the long-standing awareness of this trend, to my knowledge, previous work has not used it to assess the plausibility of behavioral models.
Templeton et al. (1996) considered all in vitro fertilizations in Britain from 1991 to 1994, whereas van Noord-Zaadstra et al. (1991) considered all artificial inseminations in two fertility clinics in the Netherlands during the clinic-specific period when fresh (rather than frozen) semen was used (1973–1980 for one clinic, and 1973–1986 for the other), and restricted analysis to married women whose husbands were azoospermic and who had never previously given birth or received an artificial insemination. Sample sizes are tiny in both studies for women older than 40, so the adjustment may be unreliable for these groups.
This analysis cannot rule out age-changing preferences regarding sexual variety, a possibility discussed at greater length later in this article.
One may imagine many ways by which network formation may covary with age. However, the assumptions needed for networks to create age-decreasing risks are strong. All members of a network are at similar levels of risk, so if network members are both young and old, then we have age-independence. If networks of partners are stratified by age, one could imagine a situation wherein uninfected older individuals match separately from more infected younger people. However, the dynamics of these networks are very difficult to justify. For example, if everyone in one network matches only with people born before January 1, 1970, then such a network could exist, but not if everyone matches with people who are within one or two years of his or her age.
Results are not sensitive to making this piece-wise linear specification more flexible.
The African studies cited here are from Nigeria, Uganda, Kenya, and Malawi. I am not aware of a similar documentation in South Africa. However, given that researchers frequently hypothesize that it is exposure to Western culture and the development process that leads to this shift, we may expect the courtship and marriage paradigm to be at least as important in South Africa as in other parts of Africa.
Individuals in this model draw only one partner at a time. Although age-independent concurrencies perform poorly against the age-risk profile, search with multiple concurrent draws would have similar predictions to this model, with even more severe implications for epidemic prevalence.
In a more sophisticated model, individuals may consider the state and future path of the HIV epidemic in making their spousal choices. However, if individuals have rational beliefs about HIV, the distortion in behavior is minimal. Because early in a relationship, the risk from drawing a new partner is extremely close to the risk from staying with the current partner, individuals are only very marginally willing to lower their reservation in response. Given that the rational difference is extremely small and that I have no way to assess what South Africans actually believe about the transmission rate or the future path of the epidemic, I abstract from this analysis.
Koopman et al.’s (1997) model is a more traditional epidemiological model than the one described here and as such differs strongly in focus. There, transitions between phases of high and low sexual activity are not brought about by any behavioral process but rather by outcomes of exogenous (and calibrated) chance. Similarly, systematic matching between individuals in different phases is specified rather than the outcome of a behavioral process like spousal search. This makes it more difficult to derive policy predictions like those employed in this article because the motivations for risky behavior are not identified. Koopman et al. also assumed a higher transmission rate and an order of magnitude more partners than those employed here, with individuals in their model accumulating a staggering two new partners per month.
I chose 1/6 because in simulations, about one-sixth of single, HIV-positive individual-months are spent in acute infection for those who don’t enter already infected. Varying this fraction has only a small impact on results.
It is natural to suspect that coital frequencies decline as people become increasingly sick in mature infection. Wawer et al. (2005) followed transmission rates and coital frequencies approaching death and found that coital frequencies decline gradually over 6–30 months before death, from a rate of 10.0 coital acts per month earlier in infection to a rate of 8.7 coital acts per month in months 16–25 before death and 6.2 acts per month 6 months before death. However, transmission rates increase faster than coital frequencies decline, and Wawer et al. documented that transmission occurs about 3.65 times as frequently over months 6–30 prior to death. I use that frequency in my calibration.
Because cohorts of simulated partners must build up over time, HIV entry is delayed to minimize the effects of time dynamics in homophily in age. (Simulations suggest that this time delay has a slight and conservative effect on HIV prevalence.) In fact, the role of age-specific homophily in the spread of HIV is somewhat unclear. If people match nonrandomly with others in a similar age category, this may lead to more explosiveness in the HIV epidemic as people in high turnover phases with greater likelihood of acute infection match systematically with others in the same phase. This observation makes the role of homophily in the spread of HIV an important avenue for future research, particularly as it interacts with messages about relative risks (Dupas 2011), which persuade girls that older men have higher prevalence and, hence, that younger boyfriends are safer. Fortunately, the lower pregnancy rates found by Dupas for girlfriends of young and presumably high-turnover boys suggest that lower fertility demand may overwhelm this concern.
This is true to a gross approximation. With most specifications, the declining reservation quality with age is relatively slight until very near mortality; this has consequences for marginal relationships only (although the odds of marriage can be boosted by not terminating during a few stochastically marginal periods). As I show later, when I turn transmission off at the beginnings of relationships, much of the risk that singles are exposed to enters through “bad” relationships that are easily rejected; this behavior is hardly affected by declining reservation quality with age. For example, in the preferred specification, about 71% of relationships last only one month in years 1–18 of a 20-year lifespan (SD = 0.015), based on 2,500 observations of simulated life spans, and there is no statistical age trend across these years.
These assumptions create an integer problem because the individual is then sexually active for only some fraction of the year in which she or he first has sex. Because the age at which one first has sex is the absolute earliest she or he could start risky search, I assume that young adults begin searching (and hence reach the full single risk level) in their first full year of sexual activity. However, the potential for heightened pre- and post-nuptial coital frequencies suggest that married individuals may start on the married risk rates in the year in which they get married; the figures presented reflect this assumption. Resolving the integer problem in different ways results in very similar fits.
In fact, the fit outperforms that of the current state-of-the art epidemiological model for South Africa, the ASSA (2005) AIDS model, with sum of squared deviations of about one-half the magnitude.
Except concerning the eventual marital behavior, such a model is very similar to that described in Koopman et al. (1997).
The Cape Area Panel Study Waves 1, 2, and 3 were collected between 2002 and 2005 by the University of Cape Town and the University of Michigan, with funding provided by the U.S. National Institute for Child Health and Human Development and the Andrew W. Mellon Foundation. The data set is described in further detail in Online Resource 1.
An external additional test of the model would be to input transmission dynamics of a different sexually transmitted disease in a different context and evaluate the age profile. Unfortunately, transmission probabilities of most sexually transmitted diseases are little understood, and cases of them are often undocumented. Gonorrhea in the United States, however, provides a good case study (although extremely low prevalences may cause some concern over selectivity). I complete this analysis in Online Resource 1; once again, male and female patterns are differentiable from each other and do resemble infection rates, although the fit is less close than in the HIV case, possibly because of low and nonrandom prevalence.
Other values of δ have their multiplier reduced similarly under this policy.
African PPY transmission rates are 8%–12%, which contrasts with U.S. and European rates of 5%–10%. This similarity in the face of lower condom use, more circumcision, and higher STI prevalences led Gray et al. (2001) to reject the hypothesis that HIV-1 subtypes in Africa are more infectious. Still, these similar PPY transmission rates contrast sharply with the large differences in Oster (2005), who uses a per-partnership transmission rate (Downs and De Vincenzi (1996) advocate the per-partnership measure because HIV infections do not appear to be binomial in contacts due to heterogeneity in infectiousness). This approach represents one approximation; it is imperfect because individuals do become infected several years into the described studies. No matter how transmission rates are estimated, a wide variety of point estimates are received, with per-partnership rates exhibiting a particularly high variance. This is due to factors such as differences in lengths of the studies, differences in coital frequencies, differences in the fraction of study participants who report perfect condom usage, and small sample sizes, as well as different biological transmission rates. Because of this, the most recent studies—all African—prefer per-partnership-year or per-coital act transmission rates, which this study follows.
If only a partial reduction in transmission rates is achieved, using biology to treat the epidemic is less effective. Reducing transmission rates by 12.5% (50% of what is feasible) reduces the multiplier by 1 (available from the author).
These transmission rate numbers are justified by the review in Cohen et al. (2007), which also suggests that the true transmission rate under treatment is likely closer to the 0 estimate than the 50% of latent rates; the durations of treatment are meant to provide a fairly broad range given the availability and institutional constraints in Africa.
Results are not presented because the large number of assumptions renders them fairly speculative. In particular, there is little research on the natural course of infection, which would result from a window of treatment early in the infection. Implications for drug-resistant strains may also be severe and quite negative, but they are beyond the scope of this analysis.
Adolescent girls in rural Kenya have been shown to respond to information on relative risks of different partners by changing their sexual behavior (Dupas 2011), so this message of targeted risk seems likely to be one to which individuals respond.